1 00:00:00,500 --> 00:00:01,932 [SQUEAKING] 2 00:00:01,932 --> 00:00:03,381 [RUSTLING] 3 00:00:03,381 --> 00:00:10,630 [CLICKING] 4 00:00:10,630 --> 00:00:13,250 JONATHAN GRUBER: All right, let's get started. 5 00:00:13,250 --> 00:00:16,219 Today, we're going to continue our discussion of factor 6 00:00:16,219 --> 00:00:17,400 markets. 7 00:00:17,400 --> 00:00:19,580 If you recall, last Monday, we started 8 00:00:19,580 --> 00:00:22,190 talking about the labor market. 9 00:00:22,190 --> 00:00:25,640 And we talked about how workers make the decision between work 10 00:00:25,640 --> 00:00:26,750 and leisure. 11 00:00:26,750 --> 00:00:28,340 And we talked about the implications 12 00:00:28,340 --> 00:00:31,090 for setting the wage rate in the labor market. 13 00:00:31,090 --> 00:00:33,440 What I want to do today is return to that labor market 14 00:00:33,440 --> 00:00:35,960 equilibrium and talk about the important case 15 00:00:35,960 --> 00:00:37,580 of the minimum wage. 16 00:00:37,580 --> 00:00:43,920 So today, I want to talk about the labor market equilibrium 17 00:00:43,920 --> 00:00:46,730 and how it's affected by the minimum wage 18 00:00:46,730 --> 00:00:49,670 because it's an interesting case which allows us to introduce 19 00:00:49,670 --> 00:00:52,980 some complications as to how we think about the labor market. 20 00:00:52,980 --> 00:00:55,580 So let's go back and think about the labor market. 21 00:00:55,580 --> 00:00:56,705 So let's go to figure 16-1. 22 00:00:59,283 --> 00:01:00,950 The labor market, like any other market, 23 00:01:00,950 --> 00:01:02,160 has a price and a quantity. 24 00:01:02,160 --> 00:01:03,952 The quantity is the amount of labor supply. 25 00:01:03,952 --> 00:01:05,510 That's on the x-axis. 26 00:01:05,510 --> 00:01:06,510 The price is the wage. 27 00:01:06,510 --> 00:01:08,460 That's on the y-axis. 28 00:01:08,460 --> 00:01:11,990 The supply curve that's upward sloping-- 29 00:01:11,990 --> 00:01:14,550 typically we'll assume an upward-sloping supply curve. 30 00:01:14,550 --> 00:01:17,230 But as we discussed last time, that doesn't have to be true. 31 00:01:17,230 --> 00:01:19,750 If income effects dominate substitution effects, which 32 00:01:19,750 --> 00:01:22,310 they very well may, you could actually 33 00:01:22,310 --> 00:01:26,840 have a backward-bending or downward-sloping supply curve. 34 00:01:26,840 --> 00:01:28,490 So we talked about that last time. 35 00:01:28,490 --> 00:01:30,093 Having taught that interesting case, 36 00:01:30,093 --> 00:01:31,760 typically, we'll assume supply is upward 37 00:01:31,760 --> 00:01:34,790 sloping or at least not backwards bending, 38 00:01:34,790 --> 00:01:36,770 not downward sloping. 39 00:01:36,770 --> 00:01:38,342 But remember, that's an assumption. 40 00:01:38,342 --> 00:01:39,800 So this upward-sloping supply curve 41 00:01:39,800 --> 00:01:43,730 is not necessarily as obvious as a downward-sloping demand 42 00:01:43,730 --> 00:01:44,440 curve is. 43 00:01:44,440 --> 00:01:46,190 Downward-sloping demand will almost always 44 00:01:46,190 --> 00:01:47,648 exist unless there's a weird Giffen 45 00:01:47,648 --> 00:01:49,580 good, whereas upward-sloping supply is 46 00:01:49,580 --> 00:01:51,297 a little more questionable. 47 00:01:51,297 --> 00:01:53,630 So we have the equilibrium, and we have this equilibrium 48 00:01:53,630 --> 00:01:57,200 at L1 workers at a wage W1. 49 00:01:57,200 --> 00:01:58,830 So now we know where this comes from. 50 00:01:58,830 --> 00:02:00,470 So basically, going all the way back 51 00:02:00,470 --> 00:02:03,560 to producer theory where we just gave you a W, 52 00:02:03,560 --> 00:02:05,295 now we're telling where the W comes from. 53 00:02:05,295 --> 00:02:07,670 We're telling you where the wage comes from that you then 54 00:02:07,670 --> 00:02:11,270 plug into the firm's optimization for them 55 00:02:11,270 --> 00:02:13,910 to produce goods. 56 00:02:13,910 --> 00:02:16,880 Now, let's imagine that we have a minimum wage. 57 00:02:16,880 --> 00:02:18,020 So let's go to figure 16-2. 58 00:02:18,020 --> 00:02:21,230 So this is a regulation which says 59 00:02:21,230 --> 00:02:23,150 that you're not allowed to pay workers 60 00:02:23,150 --> 00:02:26,460 below some minimum level. 61 00:02:26,460 --> 00:02:30,590 And let's say we set that minimum wage at the level W2 62 00:02:30,590 --> 00:02:33,470 above the market wage W1. 63 00:02:33,470 --> 00:02:34,490 Quick question. 64 00:02:34,490 --> 00:02:36,260 What would happen if we passed a law 65 00:02:36,260 --> 00:02:39,623 and set a minimum wage that was below W1? 66 00:02:39,623 --> 00:02:41,290 So there'd be a regulation which insists 67 00:02:41,290 --> 00:02:45,400 you couldn't pay workers below W2, but W2 is below W1. 68 00:02:45,400 --> 00:02:48,040 What would that do to the labor market? 69 00:02:48,040 --> 00:02:48,700 Nothing. 70 00:02:48,700 --> 00:02:50,500 And here's the key point. 71 00:02:50,500 --> 00:02:52,720 Markets in economics will always endeavor 72 00:02:52,720 --> 00:02:55,450 to avoid government regulations if they can. 73 00:02:55,450 --> 00:02:58,720 So if a government regulation is not binding, it won't matter. 74 00:02:58,720 --> 00:03:00,755 Markets will just avoid it. 75 00:03:00,755 --> 00:03:03,130 So the interesting case is only where the minimum wage is 76 00:03:03,130 --> 00:03:08,140 binding, as in the figure 16-2. 77 00:03:08,140 --> 00:03:08,890 So what happens? 78 00:03:08,890 --> 00:03:12,770 Well, if you set a minimum wage at W2, 79 00:03:12,770 --> 00:03:16,718 workers at that high wage would love to work a lot. 80 00:03:16,718 --> 00:03:17,510 That's a high wage. 81 00:03:17,510 --> 00:03:18,980 They're high in the supply curve. 82 00:03:18,980 --> 00:03:22,670 They would like to work L sub s hours. 83 00:03:22,670 --> 00:03:24,380 They would like to supply L sub s amount 84 00:03:24,380 --> 00:03:26,450 of labor supply to the market. 85 00:03:26,450 --> 00:03:29,240 Firms, however, if forced to pay a high wage, 86 00:03:29,240 --> 00:03:32,290 W2, are going to say, wait, I'm only 87 00:03:32,290 --> 00:03:35,980 going to pay that high wage if the marginal revenue product 88 00:03:35,980 --> 00:03:37,450 of labor is sufficiently high. 89 00:03:37,450 --> 00:03:39,010 Remember, we talked about the marginal revenue of product 90 00:03:39,010 --> 00:03:39,760 last time. 91 00:03:39,760 --> 00:03:42,643 It's the marginal product of labor times the price. 92 00:03:42,643 --> 00:03:44,310 So if you're going to raise the wage I'm 93 00:03:44,310 --> 00:03:47,680 going to have to pay workers, unless that affects the market 94 00:03:47,680 --> 00:03:50,590 price, I'm going to need to have a higher marginal product 95 00:03:50,590 --> 00:03:52,030 of labor, right? 96 00:03:52,030 --> 00:03:54,100 The demand equation was, I said, the wage 97 00:03:54,100 --> 00:03:57,315 equal to the marginal product of labor times the price. 98 00:03:57,315 --> 00:03:58,690 Well, if the price hasn't changed 99 00:03:58,690 --> 00:04:00,302 with the minimum wage going in, I'm 100 00:04:00,302 --> 00:04:02,260 going to need a high-- if the wage is forced up 101 00:04:02,260 --> 00:04:04,420 by the minimum wage, I'm going to need a higher 102 00:04:04,420 --> 00:04:05,860 marginal product of labor. 103 00:04:05,860 --> 00:04:08,200 How do I get a higher marginal product of labor? 104 00:04:08,200 --> 00:04:11,620 By hiring less workers because the marginal product of labor's 105 00:04:11,620 --> 00:04:12,920 diminishing. 106 00:04:12,920 --> 00:04:15,220 So if you're going to force me to pay a higher wage, 107 00:04:15,220 --> 00:04:16,959 you're going to force me to only hire workers 108 00:04:16,959 --> 00:04:18,910 until the point where the marginal product of labor 109 00:04:18,910 --> 00:04:20,800 justifies that higher wage, which means I'm 110 00:04:20,800 --> 00:04:22,870 going to hire fewer workers. 111 00:04:22,870 --> 00:04:26,110 So firms demand only L sub d. 112 00:04:26,110 --> 00:04:29,270 Well, workers can't get jobs firms don't want to give. 113 00:04:29,270 --> 00:04:36,760 So the equilibrium is L sub d jobs at a wage W sub 2, OK? 114 00:04:36,760 --> 00:04:38,350 What does this do to welfare? 115 00:04:38,350 --> 00:04:42,070 We can see before, before the minimum wage was in place, 116 00:04:42,070 --> 00:04:46,750 the market featured a consumer surplus that-- here, consumers 117 00:04:46,750 --> 00:04:48,010 are firms, right? 118 00:04:48,010 --> 00:04:51,190 But there was a consumer surplus of A plus B plus C. 119 00:04:51,190 --> 00:04:53,410 That is, firms were willing to pay 120 00:04:53,410 --> 00:04:55,030 what was on the demand curve. 121 00:04:55,030 --> 00:04:56,950 They only had to pay W1. 122 00:04:56,950 --> 00:05:00,830 So their surplus was A plus B plus C. 123 00:05:00,830 --> 00:05:04,700 Workers were willing to work at a wage that's given 124 00:05:04,700 --> 00:05:07,130 by the supply curve S sub 1. 125 00:05:07,130 --> 00:05:09,380 They were paid at W sub 1. 126 00:05:09,380 --> 00:05:11,960 So they got a surplus of D plus E. 127 00:05:11,960 --> 00:05:14,240 So here, the firms get the consumer surplus. 128 00:05:14,240 --> 00:05:15,800 The workers get the producer surplus 129 00:05:15,800 --> 00:05:18,360 because the workers are now the producers. 130 00:05:18,360 --> 00:05:21,430 Now let's say you roll in a set minimum wage. 131 00:05:21,430 --> 00:05:24,230 Well, two things have happened. 132 00:05:24,230 --> 00:05:26,770 One thing is you've then transferred some resources 133 00:05:26,770 --> 00:05:27,640 to workers. 134 00:05:27,640 --> 00:05:31,570 That's the area B. You've taken the area B that firms used 135 00:05:31,570 --> 00:05:33,310 to get, and now workers get it. 136 00:05:33,310 --> 00:05:34,070 That's the idea. 137 00:05:34,070 --> 00:05:36,040 You want to make workers better off. 138 00:05:36,040 --> 00:05:39,230 So you transferred to workers the area B. 139 00:05:39,230 --> 00:05:42,350 On the other hand, you've created a deadweight loss 140 00:05:42,350 --> 00:05:45,590 of the area C plus E. You've created 141 00:05:45,590 --> 00:05:47,340 deadweight loss in the area C plus E 142 00:05:47,340 --> 00:05:50,100 because now there are fewer jobs. 143 00:05:50,100 --> 00:05:51,930 There are workers who would happily 144 00:05:51,930 --> 00:05:56,480 work at a higher wage who are not 145 00:05:56,480 --> 00:05:59,180 being allowed to work by the limited demand that 146 00:05:59,180 --> 00:06:01,940 comes from the minimum wage. 147 00:06:01,940 --> 00:06:06,830 So the bottom line is you end up with fewer workers, a higher 148 00:06:06,830 --> 00:06:09,230 wage, and ambiguous welfare implications. 149 00:06:09,230 --> 00:06:12,480 Clearly, social welfare goes down. 150 00:06:12,480 --> 00:06:14,370 Whether worker welfare goes up or not 151 00:06:14,370 --> 00:06:17,010 depends a bit on the size of area B versus the size of area 152 00:06:17,010 --> 00:06:20,730 E. It's not clear if worker surplus goes up or not. 153 00:06:20,730 --> 00:06:23,160 It depends on size of B versus E. In this diagram, 154 00:06:23,160 --> 00:06:26,710 workers are a net better off, but it doesn't have to be true. 155 00:06:26,710 --> 00:06:29,700 What's clear is that social welfare has gone down. 156 00:06:29,700 --> 00:06:31,200 Because remember, as I talked about, 157 00:06:31,200 --> 00:06:33,408 the cheat, the shortcut I talked about when we talked 158 00:06:33,408 --> 00:06:35,430 about oligopoly, is, roughly speaking, 159 00:06:35,430 --> 00:06:39,330 welfare is proportional to the quantity in the market. 160 00:06:39,330 --> 00:06:40,830 Essentially, the further you deviate 161 00:06:40,830 --> 00:06:43,230 from the perfectly competitive quantity, 162 00:06:43,230 --> 00:06:45,263 the bigger the deadweight loss. 163 00:06:45,263 --> 00:06:47,430 So that's what happens if you put in a minimum wage. 164 00:06:47,430 --> 00:06:50,050 Questions about that? 165 00:06:50,050 --> 00:06:50,700 OK? 166 00:06:50,700 --> 00:06:51,820 Well, that seems pretty straightforward, 167 00:06:51,820 --> 00:06:53,320 and that's what I learned growing up 168 00:06:53,320 --> 00:06:55,420 as a kid in economics class. 169 00:06:55,420 --> 00:06:58,432 But then some empirical economists, some very famous 170 00:06:58,432 --> 00:06:59,890 empirical economists, started doing 171 00:06:59,890 --> 00:07:03,340 a series of articles that actually studied, gee, 172 00:07:03,340 --> 00:07:07,030 what happens when the minimum wage does change. 173 00:07:07,030 --> 00:07:08,590 They did things like, for example, 174 00:07:08,590 --> 00:07:11,290 comparing what happened when New Jersey raised 175 00:07:11,290 --> 00:07:14,500 its minimum wage but the state of Pennsylvania next door 176 00:07:14,500 --> 00:07:18,433 did not, and looked at fast food workers in New Jersey, 177 00:07:18,433 --> 00:07:20,100 where the minimum wage went up, compared 178 00:07:20,100 --> 00:07:22,180 to fast food workers in Pennsylvania 179 00:07:22,180 --> 00:07:24,310 where the minimum wage didn't go up. 180 00:07:24,310 --> 00:07:27,040 And what they found was there was no difference 181 00:07:27,040 --> 00:07:30,850 in employment, that jobs didn't fall in New Jersey 182 00:07:30,850 --> 00:07:34,180 even though the minimum wage went up. 183 00:07:34,180 --> 00:07:35,680 And a series of follow-on studies 184 00:07:35,680 --> 00:07:38,860 continue to find that, actually, higher minimum wages didn't 185 00:07:38,860 --> 00:07:42,560 seem to cause jobs to fall, which is directly 186 00:07:42,560 --> 00:07:45,300 in contradiction with this graph. 187 00:07:45,300 --> 00:07:46,130 So what's going on? 188 00:07:46,130 --> 00:07:47,855 That led to a big question and revision 189 00:07:47,855 --> 00:07:50,930 of what's going on in these markets that leads to that. 190 00:07:50,930 --> 00:07:52,970 And there's really three possibilities 191 00:07:52,970 --> 00:07:54,590 for what's going on. 192 00:07:54,590 --> 00:07:58,270 Possibility one is that the minimum wage wasn't binding. 193 00:08:00,910 --> 00:08:05,370 Maybe New Jersey set a minimum wage below the market wage. 194 00:08:05,370 --> 00:08:07,540 But actually, empirically, that's not true. 195 00:08:07,540 --> 00:08:10,140 We can look at what workers were paid before the minimum wage. 196 00:08:10,140 --> 00:08:12,180 It was well below where the minimum wage was 197 00:08:12,180 --> 00:08:14,190 set for restaurant workers that were studied 198 00:08:14,190 --> 00:08:16,367 in that most famous study. 199 00:08:16,367 --> 00:08:17,200 So this is not true. 200 00:08:17,200 --> 00:08:20,280 The minimum wage was binding. 201 00:08:20,280 --> 00:08:21,900 There's a second possibility that's 202 00:08:21,900 --> 00:08:25,710 absolutely consistent with a perfectly competitive market. 203 00:08:25,710 --> 00:08:27,470 What's a possible answer for why I 204 00:08:27,470 --> 00:08:29,970 could impose a minimum wage in a perfectly competitive labor 205 00:08:29,970 --> 00:08:32,881 market and have employment not go down? 206 00:08:32,881 --> 00:08:33,381 Yeah? 207 00:08:33,381 --> 00:08:35,370 AUDIENCE: Price goes up. 208 00:08:35,370 --> 00:08:37,780 JONATHAN GRUBER: The price that the firm charges goes up. 209 00:08:37,780 --> 00:08:39,530 But in a perfect competitive labor market, 210 00:08:39,530 --> 00:08:42,480 that still wouldn't happen. 211 00:08:42,480 --> 00:08:43,980 You might see some price adjustment, 212 00:08:43,980 --> 00:08:45,438 but you'd still see some adjustment 213 00:08:45,438 --> 00:08:46,830 in the marginal product of labor. 214 00:08:46,830 --> 00:08:48,110 But what else about this diagram? 215 00:08:48,110 --> 00:08:48,640 Yeah. 216 00:08:48,640 --> 00:08:51,952 AUDIENCE: The firm's demand for labor is perfectly inelastic. 217 00:08:51,952 --> 00:08:54,160 JONATHAN GRUBER: The firm's-- actually, you're close. 218 00:08:54,160 --> 00:08:57,690 It'd be the worker's supply of labor is perfectly inelastic. 219 00:08:57,690 --> 00:08:58,620 It's the right idea. 220 00:08:58,620 --> 00:09:01,170 If workers are perfectly inelastic in their supply 221 00:09:01,170 --> 00:09:03,540 of labor, then the same amount of workers 222 00:09:03,540 --> 00:09:06,110 will work no matter what the wage. 223 00:09:06,110 --> 00:09:12,290 So basically, you're just going to essentially end up-- 224 00:09:12,290 --> 00:09:14,290 you'd also, in fact-- that's a good point-- also 225 00:09:14,290 --> 00:09:15,832 get inelastic demand, the same thing. 226 00:09:19,360 --> 00:09:21,370 If either supply or demand is inelastic, 227 00:09:21,370 --> 00:09:24,450 you'll end up with no effect of a minimum wage. 228 00:09:24,450 --> 00:09:25,920 So that's another possibility. 229 00:09:25,920 --> 00:09:27,890 But in fact, we've done a lot of studies. 230 00:09:27,890 --> 00:09:34,970 So you could have inelastic supply or demand. 231 00:09:34,970 --> 00:09:37,810 But in fact, we've done lots of studies of supply and demand 232 00:09:37,810 --> 00:09:40,810 in these markets, and that's not true. 233 00:09:40,810 --> 00:09:43,060 Remember, supply was largely inelastic for men, 234 00:09:43,060 --> 00:09:46,030 but it was somewhat elastic for women. 235 00:09:46,030 --> 00:09:47,500 And these low-income markets have 236 00:09:47,500 --> 00:09:50,050 a good mix of men and women working in them. 237 00:09:50,050 --> 00:09:52,270 Demand has been shown to be somewhat elastic. 238 00:09:52,270 --> 00:09:54,850 So neither supply nor demand's very elastic, 239 00:09:54,850 --> 00:09:58,040 but they're sufficiently elastic that that rules out as zero. 240 00:09:58,040 --> 00:10:01,880 So the third possibility and the one economists have focused on 241 00:10:01,880 --> 00:10:05,070 is that we're not in a competitive labor market. 242 00:10:05,070 --> 00:10:13,060 They're focused on a noncompetitive labor market. 243 00:10:13,060 --> 00:10:16,150 Just like we discussed noncompetitive markets 244 00:10:16,150 --> 00:10:19,120 for goods with a monopoly and oligopoly, 245 00:10:19,120 --> 00:10:22,990 you can have noncompetitive markets for labor. 246 00:10:22,990 --> 00:10:26,260 It's the basic same idea. 247 00:10:26,260 --> 00:10:28,460 So now let's look at-- 248 00:10:28,460 --> 00:10:30,260 so when we thought about-- let's go back, 249 00:10:30,260 --> 00:10:31,570 think about perfect competition, the basics 250 00:10:31,570 --> 00:10:32,848 of perfect competition. 251 00:10:32,848 --> 00:10:34,390 We thought about perfect competition. 252 00:10:34,390 --> 00:10:36,700 The basic idea was, remember, I talked about laying out 253 00:10:36,700 --> 00:10:40,330 a bunch of rugs in a market where you could literally 254 00:10:40,330 --> 00:10:42,760 shop costlessly across all the people selling 255 00:10:42,760 --> 00:10:46,450 their little fake Eiffel towers, little statue Eiffel towers. 256 00:10:46,450 --> 00:10:47,680 And you could perfectly shop. 257 00:10:47,680 --> 00:10:50,125 It was easy to go from carpet to carpet. 258 00:10:50,125 --> 00:10:51,250 There was full information. 259 00:10:51,250 --> 00:10:52,760 The prices were posted. 260 00:10:52,760 --> 00:10:54,760 And so basically what you ended up 261 00:10:54,760 --> 00:10:59,680 was perfectly elastic demand facing any given firm. 262 00:10:59,680 --> 00:11:01,780 Any given firm, if they tried to charge 263 00:11:01,780 --> 00:11:05,630 one cent more for their Eiffel tower, no one would buy it. 264 00:11:05,630 --> 00:11:08,980 If they charged one cent less, they'd immediately run out. 265 00:11:08,980 --> 00:11:10,420 Everyone'd buy it. 266 00:11:10,420 --> 00:11:12,787 Well, when we are modeling labor markets-- 267 00:11:12,787 --> 00:11:14,870 and I discussed this last time, but not very well. 268 00:11:14,870 --> 00:11:16,240 So I want to come back to it. 269 00:11:16,240 --> 00:11:17,980 When we're modeling labor markets, 270 00:11:17,980 --> 00:11:21,560 we're thinking about the same feature of perfect competition. 271 00:11:21,560 --> 00:11:28,820 But here, it's not consumers shopping 272 00:11:28,820 --> 00:11:30,320 over where to buy their goods. 273 00:11:30,320 --> 00:11:34,040 It's workers shopping over where to work. 274 00:11:34,040 --> 00:11:36,980 It's workers saying, gee, in a perfectly competitive labor 275 00:11:36,980 --> 00:11:41,180 market, the idea is I know what I could earn at any firm 276 00:11:41,180 --> 00:11:43,130 and I can easily shop across firms, 277 00:11:43,130 --> 00:11:44,690 see where I'm going to work. 278 00:11:44,690 --> 00:11:48,020 So if any firm tried to pay me one cent less than the market 279 00:11:48,020 --> 00:11:50,230 wage, I'd never work there. 280 00:11:50,230 --> 00:11:53,090 And if they tried to pay me one cent more than the market wage, 281 00:11:53,090 --> 00:11:55,710 every worker in the world would want to work there. 282 00:11:55,710 --> 00:11:58,100 So in a perfectly competitive labor market, 283 00:11:58,100 --> 00:12:03,410 any given firm faces a perfectly elastic supply of labor. 284 00:12:03,410 --> 00:12:06,481 So we can see that in figure 16-4, 285 00:12:06,481 --> 00:12:09,064 which we actually showed-- and I'll let you skip this since we 286 00:12:09,064 --> 00:12:09,564 covered it-- 287 00:12:09,564 --> 00:12:12,410 16-4, which I actually showed in the last lecture. 288 00:12:12,410 --> 00:12:14,510 Remember the last lecture. 289 00:12:14,510 --> 00:12:16,820 I was focused on this downward-sloping demand curve, 290 00:12:16,820 --> 00:12:19,430 but I casually threw in this flat labor supply curve 291 00:12:19,430 --> 00:12:21,080 and botched explaining it. 292 00:12:21,080 --> 00:12:23,720 Now I'm explaining it, hopefully more clearly, which 293 00:12:23,720 --> 00:12:28,850 is to any given firm, the labor supply curve 294 00:12:28,850 --> 00:12:35,330 is perfectly elastic because workers can perfectly 295 00:12:35,330 --> 00:12:37,290 shop across job opportunities. 296 00:12:37,290 --> 00:12:41,450 So if that firm tried to pay less, they'd get no workers. 297 00:12:41,450 --> 00:12:46,100 So they faced a perfectly elastic supply of labor. 298 00:12:46,100 --> 00:12:48,680 But just like, in reality, there's 299 00:12:48,680 --> 00:12:51,265 no such thing as a perfectly competitive product market, 300 00:12:51,265 --> 00:12:52,640 in reality, there's no such thing 301 00:12:52,640 --> 00:12:54,770 as a perfectly competitive labor market. 302 00:12:54,770 --> 00:12:59,060 In fact, we can't shop easily across all possible jobs 303 00:12:59,060 --> 00:13:01,430 and know what every job could pay. 304 00:13:01,430 --> 00:13:06,200 And the fact that we can't means that firms on the labor market 305 00:13:06,200 --> 00:13:08,270 side will have market power. 306 00:13:08,270 --> 00:13:10,940 Just like we talked about monopolists and oligopolists 307 00:13:10,940 --> 00:13:14,620 having market power over consumers 308 00:13:14,620 --> 00:13:17,410 through barriers to entry, firms will 309 00:13:17,410 --> 00:13:21,160 have market power over workers because workers can't perfectly 310 00:13:21,160 --> 00:13:24,520 shop across their job alternatives. 311 00:13:24,520 --> 00:13:28,570 So as a result, firms may be able to get away 312 00:13:28,570 --> 00:13:32,883 with paying you less than what you might earn elsewhere. 313 00:13:32,883 --> 00:13:34,550 In a perfectly competitive labor market, 314 00:13:34,550 --> 00:13:35,930 a firm could never pay you less than what 315 00:13:35,930 --> 00:13:37,850 you're worth elsewhere because you'd just 316 00:13:37,850 --> 00:13:39,170 go work somewhere else. 317 00:13:39,170 --> 00:13:42,200 But now, if McDonald's wants to pay you less than you might get 318 00:13:42,200 --> 00:13:45,260 at Wendy's, but it's hard to go find out what Wendy's going 319 00:13:45,260 --> 00:13:47,690 to pay you-- you have to go a distance down the road, 320 00:13:47,690 --> 00:13:49,430 and you have to ask them, and you're shy 321 00:13:49,430 --> 00:13:51,950 and it's embarrassing-- then McDonald's might be able to get 322 00:13:51,950 --> 00:13:56,480 away with paying you less than you might earn at Wendy's. 323 00:13:56,480 --> 00:13:58,880 So this is very much parallel to monopoly. 324 00:13:58,880 --> 00:14:01,520 In fact, we call this a monopsony. 325 00:14:04,990 --> 00:14:08,300 A monopsony is a labor market where 326 00:14:08,300 --> 00:14:11,270 firms have market power over workers 327 00:14:11,270 --> 00:14:15,230 just like a monopoly is a goods market where firms have 328 00:14:15,230 --> 00:14:18,800 market power over consumers. 329 00:14:18,800 --> 00:14:20,900 Now, this is not so crazy. 330 00:14:20,900 --> 00:14:24,980 And in fact, it applies very much to me. 331 00:14:24,980 --> 00:14:27,350 Think about my situation at MIT. 332 00:14:27,350 --> 00:14:28,490 I've been here 25 years. 333 00:14:28,490 --> 00:14:30,130 I just got my 25th year rocking chair, 334 00:14:30,130 --> 00:14:31,880 although actually it's not a rocking chair 335 00:14:31,880 --> 00:14:34,102 because it comes in the box with the rockers off it. 336 00:14:34,102 --> 00:14:36,560 And it arrived in my office, so it's sort of a short chair. 337 00:14:36,560 --> 00:14:38,658 My wife's 5 foot, and she always complains 338 00:14:38,658 --> 00:14:39,950 how chairs are too big for her. 339 00:14:39,950 --> 00:14:41,790 So she sat, and she's like, it's a perfect chair for me. 340 00:14:41,790 --> 00:14:43,998 So now I have a nonrocking rocking chair in my office 341 00:14:43,998 --> 00:14:44,810 that she sits in. 342 00:14:44,810 --> 00:14:48,740 But anyway, I've been at MIT for 25 years. 343 00:14:48,740 --> 00:14:50,710 It's going to be really hard for me to move. 344 00:14:50,710 --> 00:14:51,845 I like my house. 345 00:14:51,845 --> 00:14:52,720 I like my colleagues. 346 00:14:52,720 --> 00:14:54,440 I like my friends. 347 00:14:54,440 --> 00:14:56,810 Kind of, I like my view out the window. 348 00:14:56,810 --> 00:14:59,090 It's going to be kind of hard for me to move. 349 00:14:59,090 --> 00:15:01,220 Moreover, it'd be pretty hard for me to figure out 350 00:15:01,220 --> 00:15:02,870 what I'd get paid if I moved. 351 00:15:02,870 --> 00:15:04,770 I can't go to other universities and say, 352 00:15:04,770 --> 00:15:06,870 hey, what would you pay me if you hired me? 353 00:15:06,870 --> 00:15:08,490 That's be awkward. 354 00:15:08,490 --> 00:15:10,490 I can't really ask my colleagues what they make. 355 00:15:10,490 --> 00:15:12,080 That's awkward. 356 00:15:12,080 --> 00:15:16,220 So at the end of the day, MIT has market power over me 357 00:15:16,220 --> 00:15:18,343 because I don't really want to move 358 00:15:18,343 --> 00:15:19,760 and I can't really figure out what 359 00:15:19,760 --> 00:15:22,070 I'd get paid if I did move. 360 00:15:22,070 --> 00:15:24,170 And MIT will exploit that market power over me 361 00:15:24,170 --> 00:15:28,280 by paying me less than I might earn elsewhere. 362 00:15:28,280 --> 00:15:32,360 And we know this as a fact because in academia, 363 00:15:32,360 --> 00:15:35,480 the only way to get a raise is to go get an offer from someone 364 00:15:35,480 --> 00:15:38,710 else and have them say how much more they'll pay you, 365 00:15:38,710 --> 00:15:41,618 and then you take that to your boss and they say, match this. 366 00:15:41,618 --> 00:15:43,160 But if you're not willing to do this, 367 00:15:43,160 --> 00:15:45,760 as, frankly, MIT knows I'm not willing to do, 368 00:15:45,760 --> 00:15:48,830 then MIT can essentially underpay me. 369 00:15:48,830 --> 00:15:53,270 So basically, any responsible profit-maximizing 370 00:15:53,270 --> 00:15:57,020 or even nonprofit employer will exploit this market power 371 00:15:57,020 --> 00:16:01,380 and they'll pay me less than my market wage. 372 00:16:01,380 --> 00:16:06,120 And that means that MIT will earn surplus on me. 373 00:16:06,120 --> 00:16:08,370 In a perfectly competitive labor market, 374 00:16:08,370 --> 00:16:10,680 the firm earns no surplus on the worker. 375 00:16:10,680 --> 00:16:14,080 They pay the worker their marginal revenue product. 376 00:16:14,080 --> 00:16:16,750 So if you go to this figure, what am I paying the worker? 377 00:16:16,750 --> 00:16:18,990 What I'm paying them is exactly the marginal revenue 378 00:16:18,990 --> 00:16:22,890 product just like, in a competitive market 379 00:16:22,890 --> 00:16:28,745 for the goods, a firm is selling at exactly their marginal cost. 380 00:16:28,745 --> 00:16:30,870 So just like a firm makes no surplus in a perfectly 381 00:16:30,870 --> 00:16:34,710 competitive goods market, a firm hiring workers 382 00:16:34,710 --> 00:16:37,270 makes no surplus in a competitive labor market. 383 00:16:37,270 --> 00:16:40,620 But in a monopsony market, the firm makes surplus over me. 384 00:16:40,620 --> 00:16:43,590 They pay me less than they'd have to because I don't shop 385 00:16:43,590 --> 00:16:47,330 and find a better opportunity. 386 00:16:47,330 --> 00:16:49,817 Now, are there questions about how that market works? 387 00:16:49,817 --> 00:16:51,650 I'm not going to do all the math and graphs. 388 00:16:51,650 --> 00:16:53,960 It's all the same as monopoly, just flipping demand and supply 389 00:16:53,960 --> 00:16:54,190 curves. 390 00:16:54,190 --> 00:16:55,340 It's a pain in the ass. 391 00:16:55,340 --> 00:16:56,390 I'm not going to do it. 392 00:16:56,390 --> 00:16:58,910 I just want you guys to understand the intuition. 393 00:16:58,910 --> 00:17:00,750 So please, since I went through this, 394 00:17:00,750 --> 00:17:04,880 are there questions about this or how it works? 395 00:17:04,880 --> 00:17:05,660 OK. 396 00:17:05,660 --> 00:17:08,045 Now let's take this noncompetitive labor market 397 00:17:08,045 --> 00:17:11,220 and let's throw in a minimum wage. 398 00:17:11,220 --> 00:17:13,859 Well, as before, if the minimum wage 399 00:17:13,859 --> 00:17:15,900 is below what the firm was already paying, 400 00:17:15,900 --> 00:17:16,947 there's no effect. 401 00:17:16,947 --> 00:17:18,780 So let's assume it's a binding minimum wage. 402 00:17:21,920 --> 00:17:26,210 Now, let's say the binding minimum wage 403 00:17:26,210 --> 00:17:29,990 is above what my true market wage would be, 404 00:17:29,990 --> 00:17:32,510 what my wage would be in the perfectly competitive market. 405 00:17:32,510 --> 00:17:34,400 So in a perfectly competitive market, 406 00:17:34,400 --> 00:17:39,110 my wage would equal my marginal revenue product of labor, 407 00:17:39,110 --> 00:17:40,550 right? 408 00:17:40,550 --> 00:17:42,530 That's in a competitive market. 409 00:17:42,530 --> 00:17:45,190 In this noncompetitive market, my wage 410 00:17:45,190 --> 00:17:48,560 is below my marginal revenue product of labor. 411 00:17:48,560 --> 00:17:51,440 Firms are exploiting me because I can't effectively 412 00:17:51,440 --> 00:17:52,677 shop for a better job. 413 00:17:52,677 --> 00:17:54,260 I don't want to or it's hard to do so. 414 00:17:56,850 --> 00:17:59,040 Now, in this noncompetitive market, 415 00:17:59,040 --> 00:18:01,560 if we set a minimum wage that's higher 416 00:18:01,560 --> 00:18:04,570 than the marginal revenue product of labor, 417 00:18:04,570 --> 00:18:08,840 then the analysis is just like it's a competitive firm. 418 00:18:08,840 --> 00:18:10,280 Once that marginal wage is higher 419 00:18:10,280 --> 00:18:12,072 than the marginal revenue product of labor, 420 00:18:12,072 --> 00:18:15,450 it's just like a competitive firm. 421 00:18:15,450 --> 00:18:16,670 So it's not that interesting. 422 00:18:16,670 --> 00:18:20,870 The interesting case is, what if the minimum wage comes in 423 00:18:20,870 --> 00:18:25,740 and it's above the wage I make but below the marginal revenue 424 00:18:25,740 --> 00:18:27,250 product of labor? 425 00:18:27,250 --> 00:18:29,910 So let's say McDonald's, someone working there 426 00:18:29,910 --> 00:18:33,030 yields a marginal revenue product of labor of $10, 427 00:18:33,030 --> 00:18:35,550 but they're only being paid $7. 428 00:18:35,550 --> 00:18:38,100 Let's say you roll in minimum wage of $9-- 429 00:18:38,100 --> 00:18:39,930 so above what they're being paid now, 430 00:18:39,930 --> 00:18:43,390 but below their actual marginal revenue product of labor. 431 00:18:43,390 --> 00:18:47,520 Will the firm fire that worker? 432 00:18:47,520 --> 00:18:49,456 Why not? 433 00:18:49,456 --> 00:18:50,908 Yeah. 434 00:18:50,908 --> 00:18:53,823 AUDIENCE: They're still paying them-- they're still making 435 00:18:53,823 --> 00:18:55,293 a profit off of that worker. 436 00:18:55,293 --> 00:18:57,210 JONATHAN GRUBER: They're still making surplus, 437 00:18:57,210 --> 00:18:59,600 which is as long as the marginal product of labor's 438 00:18:59,600 --> 00:19:02,990 bigger than the wage, they love that worker. 439 00:19:02,990 --> 00:19:07,740 So before-- so let's write down the numbers as an example. 440 00:19:07,740 --> 00:19:10,880 So imagine my marginal revenue product of labor at McDonald's 441 00:19:10,880 --> 00:19:14,660 is $10, but my wage is $7. 442 00:19:14,660 --> 00:19:18,370 And then you come and you set a minimum wage of $9. 443 00:19:18,370 --> 00:19:20,950 Well, 10 is still greater than 9. 444 00:19:20,950 --> 00:19:24,430 So the firm has no desire to fire me. 445 00:19:24,430 --> 00:19:27,130 So all you've done is just given me money. 446 00:19:27,130 --> 00:19:30,640 And where'd that money come from? 447 00:19:30,640 --> 00:19:32,700 The surplus the firm earned. 448 00:19:32,700 --> 00:19:36,330 So all you've done is shifted the surplus from-- 449 00:19:36,330 --> 00:19:38,960 you've shifted producer surplus to consumer-- 450 00:19:38,960 --> 00:19:41,980 I'm sorry, consumer surplus-- consumers are the firms-- 451 00:19:41,980 --> 00:19:44,440 to producer surplus, the workers. 452 00:19:44,440 --> 00:19:48,430 So in a monopsony market, a minimum wage 453 00:19:48,430 --> 00:19:50,350 doesn't cause deadweight loss. 454 00:19:50,350 --> 00:19:52,750 It just shifts surplus around. 455 00:19:52,750 --> 00:19:55,670 And that's a really important outcome 456 00:19:55,670 --> 00:19:58,130 because that, once again, says the government isn't 457 00:19:58,130 --> 00:20:00,500 always bad here. 458 00:20:00,500 --> 00:20:02,390 This is just like-- if you want to think 459 00:20:02,390 --> 00:20:05,240 about this graphically, go back to exactly the analysis we 460 00:20:05,240 --> 00:20:07,070 did of regulating monopolies. 461 00:20:07,070 --> 00:20:09,470 Remember we talked about regulating monopolies. 462 00:20:09,470 --> 00:20:17,810 We talked about, if a regulator comes in and sets a price 463 00:20:17,810 --> 00:20:21,680 below the monopoly price but above the competitive price, 464 00:20:21,680 --> 00:20:24,500 it reduced the deadweight loss of monopoly. 465 00:20:24,500 --> 00:20:25,410 It's the same thing. 466 00:20:25,410 --> 00:20:28,970 And if you set a minimum wage above the market wage 467 00:20:28,970 --> 00:20:31,460 but below the marginal revenue product of labor, 468 00:20:31,460 --> 00:20:33,710 then you simply transfer surplus to workers 469 00:20:33,710 --> 00:20:36,270 without causing deadweight loss. 470 00:20:36,270 --> 00:20:38,050 Now, that raised the question, of course, 471 00:20:38,050 --> 00:20:39,760 is the minimum wage in between the wage 472 00:20:39,760 --> 00:20:42,340 of the marginal product of labor? 473 00:20:42,340 --> 00:20:44,140 Well, we don't know, but let's go back 474 00:20:44,140 --> 00:20:45,910 to the studies that motivated this. 475 00:20:45,910 --> 00:20:47,440 The very fact that the minimum wage 476 00:20:47,440 --> 00:20:48,940 doesn't seem to cause unemployment 477 00:20:48,940 --> 00:20:52,900 suggests we are hitting the sweet spot, 478 00:20:52,900 --> 00:20:55,570 suggests we are hitting the sweet spot, that we're 479 00:20:55,570 --> 00:20:58,510 basically managing, with the minimum wage policy, at least 480 00:20:58,510 --> 00:21:01,570 to date, to essentially just find a way, 481 00:21:01,570 --> 00:21:03,370 without the government spending any money, 482 00:21:03,370 --> 00:21:06,700 to shift resources from businesses to workers. 483 00:21:06,700 --> 00:21:08,390 So what does this mean? 484 00:21:08,390 --> 00:21:13,090 Well, it means that around the level of current minimum wages, 485 00:21:13,090 --> 00:21:15,620 we can raise the minimum wage by a small amount pretty 486 00:21:15,620 --> 00:21:16,840 costlessly. 487 00:21:16,840 --> 00:21:20,728 It doesn't necessarily mean that a $15 minimum wage is OK. 488 00:21:20,728 --> 00:21:22,270 So in some sense, the existing-- this 489 00:21:22,270 --> 00:21:25,150 is the important thing about empirical economics. 490 00:21:25,150 --> 00:21:27,580 You only learn the answer in the range that you study it. 491 00:21:27,580 --> 00:21:29,200 So for example, there've been studies 492 00:21:29,200 --> 00:21:32,320 that have looked at what happens if you have a $10 minimum wage, 493 00:21:32,320 --> 00:21:33,848 and those show no unemployment. 494 00:21:33,848 --> 00:21:35,890 There haven't been studies that show what happens 495 00:21:35,890 --> 00:21:37,870 if you have a $15 minimum wage. 496 00:21:37,870 --> 00:21:40,720 Now, Seattle just actually put in a $15 minimum wage 497 00:21:40,720 --> 00:21:41,777 about two years ago. 498 00:21:41,777 --> 00:21:43,360 So we actually can run the experiment. 499 00:21:43,360 --> 00:21:46,590 And the early evidence is the Seattle $15 500 00:21:46,590 --> 00:21:50,390 minimum wage did lower employment, that the Seattle 501 00:21:50,390 --> 00:21:53,360 $15 minimum wage actually went above the marginal revenue 502 00:21:53,360 --> 00:21:54,830 product of labor. 503 00:21:54,830 --> 00:21:57,945 And once it's above, you're back in the competitive case. 504 00:21:57,945 --> 00:22:00,320 You're back in the case where you're lowering employment. 505 00:22:00,320 --> 00:22:00,980 Yeah? 506 00:22:00,980 --> 00:22:04,848 AUDIENCE: How can you increase competitiveness in the market? 507 00:22:04,848 --> 00:22:06,890 JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, that's the other question, 508 00:22:06,890 --> 00:22:09,200 is how could you increase-- so you tell me. 509 00:22:09,200 --> 00:22:10,950 How could you increase the competitiveness 510 00:22:10,950 --> 00:22:12,840 of a labor market? 511 00:22:12,840 --> 00:22:16,450 AUDIENCE: You make it easier to tell how much money you 512 00:22:16,450 --> 00:22:17,870 would get at each place. 513 00:22:17,870 --> 00:22:21,320 JONATHAN GRUBER: So Norway has a day every year 514 00:22:21,320 --> 00:22:24,110 they call Envy Day, which was yesterday, 515 00:22:24,110 --> 00:22:26,960 I believe, where they literally can go online and look up 516 00:22:26,960 --> 00:22:29,240 anybody's income in Norway. 517 00:22:29,240 --> 00:22:33,270 They literally make public every single person's tax return 518 00:22:33,270 --> 00:22:33,770 in Norway. 519 00:22:33,770 --> 00:22:36,540 And you can go online and look at what everybody makes. 520 00:22:36,540 --> 00:22:38,900 That would do it. 521 00:22:38,900 --> 00:22:41,150 So you could provide more information. 522 00:22:41,150 --> 00:22:43,130 You could make it easier to move between jobs. 523 00:22:43,130 --> 00:22:45,422 For example, there's a lot of restrictions in our labor 524 00:22:45,422 --> 00:22:48,110 market, like noncompete clauses, which 525 00:22:48,110 --> 00:22:49,760 say that if you work for one firm, 526 00:22:49,760 --> 00:22:51,385 you can't ever go work for another firm 527 00:22:51,385 --> 00:22:54,260 in that industry for x years. 528 00:22:54,260 --> 00:22:57,125 That gives some monopsony power to firms, et cetera. 529 00:22:57,125 --> 00:22:59,750 So we could do things which try to loosen the flow of the labor 530 00:22:59,750 --> 00:23:03,680 market, and that would close this gap between wage 531 00:23:03,680 --> 00:23:06,650 and marginal revenue product of labor. 532 00:23:06,650 --> 00:23:09,020 Now, let's go back to Seattle, just to conclude this. 533 00:23:09,020 --> 00:23:11,870 This doesn't mean the Seattle policy was a bad one. 534 00:23:11,870 --> 00:23:14,420 The bottom line is what we learned from Seattle 535 00:23:14,420 --> 00:23:20,360 was that basically, employment fell a small amount 536 00:23:20,360 --> 00:23:23,100 and a bunch of workers made a bunch more money. 537 00:23:23,100 --> 00:23:24,070 So is that good or bad? 538 00:23:24,070 --> 00:23:24,600 Well, it depends. 539 00:23:24,600 --> 00:23:26,600 If you're one of the people that lost their job, 540 00:23:26,600 --> 00:23:27,345 it's really bad. 541 00:23:27,345 --> 00:23:29,970 If you're one of the workers who got a raise up to $15 an hour, 542 00:23:29,970 --> 00:23:30,930 it's good. 543 00:23:30,930 --> 00:23:32,670 How do you weigh them against each other? 544 00:23:32,670 --> 00:23:36,400 That's exactly what we'll talk about in a couple lectures. 545 00:23:36,400 --> 00:23:39,720 So once we start talking about normative economics, 546 00:23:39,720 --> 00:23:42,480 about is a policy good or bad, there's typically trade-offs. 547 00:23:42,480 --> 00:23:43,988 And this is a classic example. 548 00:23:43,988 --> 00:23:46,530 What we're learning here is, is the minimum wage in the range 549 00:23:46,530 --> 00:23:51,930 we are now, right now, the federal minimum wage at $7.25-- 550 00:23:51,930 --> 00:23:55,020 the evidence suggests it could easily rise 551 00:23:55,020 --> 00:23:56,767 without causing that trade-off. 552 00:23:56,767 --> 00:23:58,350 The evidence suggest we could increase 553 00:23:58,350 --> 00:24:02,120 the federal minimum wage by some nontrivial amount, 554 00:24:02,120 --> 00:24:04,980 at least up to $9 or $10, without causing 555 00:24:04,980 --> 00:24:06,150 much of a trade-off. 556 00:24:06,150 --> 00:24:07,800 But once you get too far ahead of that, 557 00:24:07,800 --> 00:24:09,817 there starts to be a trade-off. 558 00:24:09,817 --> 00:24:10,650 Question about that? 559 00:24:10,650 --> 00:24:11,200 Yeah. 560 00:24:11,200 --> 00:24:14,360 AUDIENCE: Are there any states where it's actually still 561 00:24:14,360 --> 00:24:14,987 that low? 562 00:24:14,987 --> 00:24:16,070 JONATHAN GRUBER: Oh, yeah. 563 00:24:16,070 --> 00:24:18,650 Many states don't have their own minimum wage. 564 00:24:18,650 --> 00:24:22,242 Massachusetts is at $11, but we're pretty unusual. 565 00:24:22,242 --> 00:24:23,450 We're one of the higher ones. 566 00:24:23,450 --> 00:24:27,990 A number of states have $7.25 as the minimum wage, OK? 567 00:24:27,990 --> 00:24:30,490 And the evidence seems to be, from states like Massachusetts 568 00:24:30,490 --> 00:24:33,138 and others which are on the $10, $11 range, it doesn't 569 00:24:33,138 --> 00:24:34,180 seem to lower employment. 570 00:24:34,180 --> 00:24:35,680 It seems like we could clearly-- 571 00:24:35,680 --> 00:24:37,960 we'd be safe raising that federal minimum wage. 572 00:24:37,960 --> 00:24:41,325 We would simply be transferring resources and not 573 00:24:41,325 --> 00:24:42,200 causing unemployment. 574 00:24:42,200 --> 00:24:42,788 Yeah? 575 00:24:42,788 --> 00:24:44,860 AUDIENCE: Is there anything about the cost 576 00:24:44,860 --> 00:24:47,530 of living in areas where the minimum wage is more expensive? 577 00:24:47,530 --> 00:24:51,340 Is it possible that if a McDonald's worker makes 578 00:24:51,340 --> 00:24:53,256 more money in this state, McDonald's is 579 00:24:53,256 --> 00:24:54,040 more expensive in that state? 580 00:24:54,040 --> 00:24:55,748 JONATHAN GRUBER: That's a great question. 581 00:24:55,748 --> 00:24:58,600 So what I assumed was I assumed firms would just say, 582 00:24:58,600 --> 00:24:59,800 oh, you got me. 583 00:24:59,800 --> 00:25:01,900 I'm going to throw some of my profits at workers. 584 00:25:01,900 --> 00:25:02,770 Firms don't have to do that. 585 00:25:02,770 --> 00:25:04,330 Firms could say, well, if you make me pay workers more, 586 00:25:04,330 --> 00:25:06,070 I'm going to raise my price. 587 00:25:06,070 --> 00:25:09,310 Now, if it's a competitive output market, 588 00:25:09,310 --> 00:25:11,350 that shouldn't happen, right? 589 00:25:11,350 --> 00:25:15,270 Because in a competitive output market-- 590 00:25:15,270 --> 00:25:15,790 well, no. 591 00:25:15,790 --> 00:25:16,780 Marginal cost goes up. 592 00:25:16,780 --> 00:25:17,470 It's not clear. 593 00:25:17,470 --> 00:25:19,470 It's not clear whether that would happen or not, 594 00:25:19,470 --> 00:25:21,070 and the evidence is that it's unclear 595 00:25:21,070 --> 00:25:22,750 whether higher minimum wage causes higher prices 596 00:25:22,750 --> 00:25:24,417 or whether it just comes out of profits. 597 00:25:24,417 --> 00:25:25,860 We don't know yet, OK? 598 00:25:25,860 --> 00:25:28,360 All right, so that's what I want to say about labor markets. 599 00:25:28,360 --> 00:25:30,568 Now I want to move on and talk about capital markets. 600 00:25:35,490 --> 00:25:38,450 Now, as confusing as our discussion of labor markets 601 00:25:38,450 --> 00:25:40,470 was, that's easy compared to capital markets. 602 00:25:40,470 --> 00:25:42,860 Capital market's a lot harder to understand. 603 00:25:42,860 --> 00:25:45,137 And that's because capital itself-- 604 00:25:45,137 --> 00:25:46,970 labor's something you get your hands around. 605 00:25:46,970 --> 00:25:49,130 It's the time you spend at work. 606 00:25:49,130 --> 00:25:51,440 Capital is this sort of amorphous thing 607 00:25:51,440 --> 00:25:53,630 that I've kept pushing off defining. 608 00:25:53,630 --> 00:25:55,012 So I'll define it now. 609 00:25:55,012 --> 00:25:57,470 We talk about capital as this vague collection of buildings 610 00:25:57,470 --> 00:26:01,190 and machines and the other stuff that goes into production. 611 00:26:01,190 --> 00:26:03,240 And we know where labor comes from. 612 00:26:03,240 --> 00:26:04,730 It comes from our work. 613 00:26:04,730 --> 00:26:07,140 But where does capital come from? 614 00:26:07,140 --> 00:26:09,900 Well, capital is a harder concept, 615 00:26:09,900 --> 00:26:14,070 but there's one unifying thread that all elements of capital 616 00:26:14,070 --> 00:26:17,820 have, which is they represent the diversion 617 00:26:17,820 --> 00:26:22,990 of current consumption towards future consumption. 618 00:26:22,990 --> 00:26:26,920 Capital is about diverting consuming today 619 00:26:26,920 --> 00:26:30,000 towards consuming in the future. 620 00:26:30,000 --> 00:26:33,380 In fact, the original concept of capital came from farmers. 621 00:26:33,380 --> 00:26:38,400 Farmers, every year, when they would pick their grain, 622 00:26:38,400 --> 00:26:39,150 they had a choice. 623 00:26:39,150 --> 00:26:41,180 They could eat all the grain, or they 624 00:26:41,180 --> 00:26:44,860 could save some to plant for next year's grain. 625 00:26:44,860 --> 00:26:48,050 Now, the more they saved, the more they'd have next year, 626 00:26:48,050 --> 00:26:50,290 but the less they'd have today. 627 00:26:50,290 --> 00:26:52,390 So farmers faced a trade-off-- 628 00:26:52,390 --> 00:26:56,030 literally, consumption today or consumption next year. 629 00:26:56,030 --> 00:26:57,520 That's what we mean by capital. 630 00:26:57,520 --> 00:27:01,090 In other words, in today's market economy, 631 00:27:01,090 --> 00:27:04,240 the link is not that direct, but it's the same basic idea-- 632 00:27:04,240 --> 00:27:07,870 that firms have a choice, firms and their investors 633 00:27:07,870 --> 00:27:09,140 have a choice. 634 00:27:09,140 --> 00:27:12,400 They can take what they make and eat it now, 635 00:27:12,400 --> 00:27:17,240 or they can invest it in having more in the future. 636 00:27:17,240 --> 00:27:20,507 So basically, when we think about capital, 637 00:27:20,507 --> 00:27:22,965 we're not going to think about capital as physical capital. 638 00:27:22,965 --> 00:27:26,030 We're really thinking about capital as financial capital. 639 00:27:26,030 --> 00:27:30,740 What links all types of capital is their financial aspect. 640 00:27:30,740 --> 00:27:33,470 What links machines and buildings is all the aspect 641 00:27:33,470 --> 00:27:36,600 that, by putting money into them today, 642 00:27:36,600 --> 00:27:39,690 you have less you can spend on fun stuff today, 643 00:27:39,690 --> 00:27:42,330 but more you'll be able to spend tomorrow. 644 00:27:42,330 --> 00:27:43,890 And it's this financial aspect that 645 00:27:43,890 --> 00:27:47,080 links all forms of capital. 646 00:27:47,080 --> 00:27:49,420 Now, how do firms get the money to invest 647 00:27:49,420 --> 00:27:51,720 in machines and buildings and stuff like that? 648 00:27:51,720 --> 00:27:55,950 They get it through going to the capital market. 649 00:27:55,950 --> 00:27:58,830 Where do firms get this money that they invest? 650 00:27:58,830 --> 00:28:02,550 They get it through going to the capital market, which 651 00:28:02,550 --> 00:28:06,060 is basically the pool of money that firms can draw on 652 00:28:06,060 --> 00:28:08,835 to make their investments. 653 00:28:08,835 --> 00:28:10,460 So think of it literally as I'm a firm. 654 00:28:10,460 --> 00:28:12,335 I want to build a building and buy a machine. 655 00:28:12,335 --> 00:28:14,860 I literally go over, and there's a big pool of money. 656 00:28:14,860 --> 00:28:18,710 And I have to take the money out of there to go buy my machine 657 00:28:18,710 --> 00:28:21,780 or build my building. 658 00:28:21,780 --> 00:28:25,320 And where does the money in that pool come from? 659 00:28:25,320 --> 00:28:29,940 It comes from household savings decisions. 660 00:28:29,940 --> 00:28:32,180 So the capital market is a market 661 00:28:32,180 --> 00:28:38,520 where the demand for capital comes from firm's interest 662 00:28:38,520 --> 00:28:42,030 in investing and having more in the future. 663 00:28:42,030 --> 00:28:47,110 The supply of capital comes from people's decisions to save. 664 00:28:47,110 --> 00:28:50,110 And essentially, the money firms use 665 00:28:50,110 --> 00:28:54,010 to buy stuff is borrowed from people. 666 00:28:54,010 --> 00:28:57,780 And that's the bottom line of how capital markets work. 667 00:28:57,780 --> 00:29:03,320 So just as the supply of labor that 668 00:29:03,320 --> 00:29:05,930 determines how many workers a firm can hire 669 00:29:05,930 --> 00:29:08,870 comes from your decision of how hard to work, 670 00:29:08,870 --> 00:29:11,180 the supply of capital that determines 671 00:29:11,180 --> 00:29:15,110 how many machines a firm can buy comes from your decision 672 00:29:15,110 --> 00:29:18,060 of how hard to save. 673 00:29:18,060 --> 00:29:21,840 So let's look at figure 16-5, equilibrium in capital markets. 674 00:29:25,080 --> 00:29:26,330 Let's start with the demand. 675 00:29:26,330 --> 00:29:29,060 We already talked, last lecture, demand for capital. 676 00:29:29,060 --> 00:29:32,870 The demand for capital comes from the marginal revenue 677 00:29:32,870 --> 00:29:34,610 product of capital. 678 00:29:34,610 --> 00:29:36,560 It's the marginal product of the next machine. 679 00:29:36,560 --> 00:29:39,410 So the demand comes from the marginal product 680 00:29:39,410 --> 00:29:41,780 of the next machine times the price the firm can 681 00:29:41,780 --> 00:29:44,270 get for its output, which is the marginal revenue 682 00:29:44,270 --> 00:29:46,430 product of capital. 683 00:29:46,430 --> 00:29:48,290 So it's the same logic as for labor. 684 00:29:48,290 --> 00:29:49,940 There's nothing interesting there. 685 00:29:49,940 --> 00:29:52,490 Same logic as for labor. 686 00:29:52,490 --> 00:29:54,830 The supply's what's more interesting here. 687 00:29:54,830 --> 00:29:56,870 Where does supply come from? 688 00:29:56,870 --> 00:30:00,440 The supply comes from household savings, 689 00:30:00,440 --> 00:30:03,610 how much money is around for firms 690 00:30:03,610 --> 00:30:06,460 to actually get to get these machines. 691 00:30:06,460 --> 00:30:07,780 And how do they get it? 692 00:30:07,780 --> 00:30:09,130 They borrow. 693 00:30:09,130 --> 00:30:10,600 And what do they borrow at? 694 00:30:10,600 --> 00:30:13,540 They borrow at the interest rate I. 695 00:30:13,540 --> 00:30:18,220 So I represents the rate that firms pay 696 00:30:18,220 --> 00:30:21,560 households to get their money. 697 00:30:21,560 --> 00:30:24,430 So think of this as-- we'll talk about how it really works. 698 00:30:24,430 --> 00:30:27,240 But in theory, the idea is think of literally a marketplace 699 00:30:27,240 --> 00:30:28,690 in the center of town. 700 00:30:28,690 --> 00:30:31,420 Downtown Boston, Haymarket, there's this marketplace. 701 00:30:31,420 --> 00:30:33,850 And a firm comes and says, I need to borrow money 702 00:30:33,850 --> 00:30:35,110 to buy a machine. 703 00:30:35,110 --> 00:30:36,830 And a person's there with their savings 704 00:30:36,830 --> 00:30:38,110 and they say, well, I'll loan you some money. 705 00:30:38,110 --> 00:30:40,030 What interest rate you going to give me? 706 00:30:40,030 --> 00:30:41,890 And that's the market for capital. 707 00:30:41,890 --> 00:30:44,800 So where the supply of capital meets the demand of capital 708 00:30:44,800 --> 00:30:47,030 yields the interest rate. 709 00:30:47,030 --> 00:30:50,820 So basically, what this means is as the interest rate's higher, 710 00:30:50,820 --> 00:30:53,660 what that means is I have to pay people back more 711 00:30:53,660 --> 00:30:54,920 to borrow their money. 712 00:30:54,920 --> 00:30:59,240 So an interest rate of 10%, if I borrow $10 from you, 713 00:30:59,240 --> 00:31:02,990 I pay you back $1.10 next period. 714 00:31:02,990 --> 00:31:05,450 If I borrow $10, I pay you back $1.10 next period. 715 00:31:05,450 --> 00:31:08,330 If the interest rate's 20%, if I borrow $10-- 716 00:31:08,330 --> 00:31:09,200 if I borrow $1-- 717 00:31:09,200 --> 00:31:09,932 I'm sorry. 718 00:31:09,932 --> 00:31:12,140 If I borrow $1 from you, I pay you $1.10 next period. 719 00:31:12,140 --> 00:31:16,450 If I have 20% and I borrow $1, I pay you back $1.20 next period, 720 00:31:16,450 --> 00:31:17,960 et cetera, OK? 721 00:31:17,960 --> 00:31:21,200 So basically, that is essentially 722 00:31:21,200 --> 00:31:22,340 how the transaction works. 723 00:31:22,340 --> 00:31:24,680 And the key point here is the reason 724 00:31:24,680 --> 00:31:27,260 the supply curve is upward sloping is 725 00:31:27,260 --> 00:31:29,300 the more you're willing to pay me for my money, 726 00:31:29,300 --> 00:31:31,250 the more I'm willing to lend you. 727 00:31:31,250 --> 00:31:33,290 So if you come to me and say give me $1 728 00:31:33,290 --> 00:31:35,960 and next year I'll give you back $1, I'm like, I don't know. 729 00:31:35,960 --> 00:31:36,793 Why would I do that? 730 00:31:36,793 --> 00:31:39,470 If you say, give me $1 and next year I'll give you back $1.10, 731 00:31:39,470 --> 00:31:41,510 you're like, OK, now I'm interested. $1.20, 732 00:31:41,510 --> 00:31:43,832 I'm very interested. $1.50, for sure. 733 00:31:43,832 --> 00:31:45,290 Literally, I just give you my money 734 00:31:45,290 --> 00:31:46,790 and, next year, I get back 50% more? 735 00:31:46,790 --> 00:31:48,470 Why not? 736 00:31:48,470 --> 00:31:50,700 So basically, the higher the interest rate, 737 00:31:50,700 --> 00:31:52,370 the more I'm willing to loan the firm 738 00:31:52,370 --> 00:31:54,662 and, therefore, you get an upward-sloping supply curve. 739 00:31:57,380 --> 00:31:59,515 Now, of course, in reality, people 740 00:31:59,515 --> 00:32:02,015 don't actually-- we don't sit in Haymarket, downtown Boston, 741 00:32:02,015 --> 00:32:03,440 and give money to firms. 742 00:32:03,440 --> 00:32:06,410 In reality, this transaction happens 743 00:32:06,410 --> 00:32:09,350 through capital markets. 744 00:32:09,350 --> 00:32:13,700 And essentially, there are three mechanisms by which implicitly 745 00:32:13,700 --> 00:32:16,820 I loan money to firms. 746 00:32:16,820 --> 00:32:24,090 The first is I could literally buy corporate debt. 747 00:32:24,090 --> 00:32:27,790 I could literally loan the money to firms. 748 00:32:27,790 --> 00:32:30,310 I could literally go and the firm could say, 749 00:32:30,310 --> 00:32:34,270 I, General Motors, am issuing a bond. 750 00:32:34,270 --> 00:32:35,980 This is through bond, issuing a bond. 751 00:32:35,980 --> 00:32:39,610 And the way that bond works is I promise that for every dollar 752 00:32:39,610 --> 00:32:43,990 you spend buying my bond, you'll get 1 plus I dollars back 753 00:32:43,990 --> 00:32:46,160 at the end-- 754 00:32:46,160 --> 00:32:49,007 or next year, say, depends on how long the bond is. 755 00:32:49,007 --> 00:32:51,590 So literally, you're loaning the money to the firm by buying-- 756 00:32:51,590 --> 00:32:54,430 you're buying their promise to pay you back. 757 00:32:54,430 --> 00:32:57,400 Now, a second way you can loan money to the firm 758 00:32:57,400 --> 00:32:59,890 is through investing in their equity. 759 00:32:59,890 --> 00:33:01,870 You can buy their stock. 760 00:33:01,870 --> 00:33:06,400 The way this works is GM says to you, buy a piece of me 761 00:33:06,400 --> 00:33:09,490 and you'll get paid back not some fixed interest rate, 762 00:33:09,490 --> 00:33:13,080 but you get paid back according to how well GM does. 763 00:33:13,080 --> 00:33:16,170 So with corporate debt, I get paid back 764 00:33:16,170 --> 00:33:18,270 something that's predetermined. 765 00:33:18,270 --> 00:33:21,210 When I buy stock or equity, I don't get back 766 00:33:21,210 --> 00:33:22,573 a predetermined amount. 767 00:33:22,573 --> 00:33:24,990 I get back some-- it depends on how well the company does. 768 00:33:24,990 --> 00:33:26,920 But it's the same basic idea. 769 00:33:26,920 --> 00:33:29,160 I'm giving the company some money today 770 00:33:29,160 --> 00:33:32,950 in return for my getting more money, I hope, tomorrow. 771 00:33:32,950 --> 00:33:34,590 That's the diversion of consumption 772 00:33:34,590 --> 00:33:36,670 from today to tomorrow. 773 00:33:36,670 --> 00:33:41,110 And the third thing I could do is I could put it in the bank. 774 00:33:41,110 --> 00:33:43,000 Now, how is that loaned to companies? 775 00:33:43,000 --> 00:33:46,210 Because the bank then loans it to companies. 776 00:33:46,210 --> 00:33:50,485 Why do banks say they'll pay you interest on your money? 777 00:33:50,485 --> 00:33:51,610 Why did banks going crazy-- 778 00:33:51,610 --> 00:33:52,327 I'll give you 1-- 779 00:33:52,327 --> 00:33:53,410 it used to be interesting. 780 00:33:53,410 --> 00:33:54,520 Now it's 1%, 2%. 781 00:33:54,520 --> 00:33:56,920 When I was a kid, I was like 10%, 12%. 782 00:33:56,920 --> 00:33:58,175 We'll give you lots of money. 783 00:33:58,175 --> 00:34:00,550 And we'll talk later about why it was so much higher when 784 00:34:00,550 --> 00:34:02,343 I was a kid. 785 00:34:02,343 --> 00:34:03,760 Why are banks so eager to do that? 786 00:34:03,760 --> 00:34:05,170 It's not out of the goodness of their heart. 787 00:34:05,170 --> 00:34:06,965 It's because when you give them dollars, they turn around 788 00:34:06,965 --> 00:34:07,870 and loan them. 789 00:34:07,870 --> 00:34:09,412 They add a bunch to the interest rate 790 00:34:09,412 --> 00:34:10,550 and loan them out to firms. 791 00:34:10,550 --> 00:34:12,580 So those dollars you're giving the banks 792 00:34:12,580 --> 00:34:14,350 and they're paying you 2% interest, 793 00:34:14,350 --> 00:34:17,580 they loan to firms at 6%. 794 00:34:17,580 --> 00:34:20,110 And that's why bankers are rich. 795 00:34:20,110 --> 00:34:22,965 So basically, the reason a bank exists is because it's a way-- 796 00:34:22,965 --> 00:34:24,340 corporate debt and equity markets 797 00:34:24,340 --> 00:34:25,955 are hard and complicated. 798 00:34:25,955 --> 00:34:27,830 It's much easier to put your money in a bank. 799 00:34:27,830 --> 00:34:28,800 You put your money in a bank. 800 00:34:28,800 --> 00:34:30,383 But when you put your money in a bank, 801 00:34:30,383 --> 00:34:32,409 you're essentially loaning it to companies. 802 00:34:32,409 --> 00:34:34,570 That's essentially what you're doing. 803 00:34:34,570 --> 00:34:38,510 So through these mechanisms, we have a capital market 804 00:34:38,510 --> 00:34:42,190 where essentially, by my putting money away and diverting 805 00:34:42,190 --> 00:34:44,235 from today's consumption, I'm loaning to a firm. 806 00:34:44,235 --> 00:34:45,610 They'll produce more, and they'll 807 00:34:45,610 --> 00:34:49,070 pay me back more in the future. 808 00:34:49,070 --> 00:34:51,889 Questions about that? 809 00:34:51,889 --> 00:34:55,170 OK, so let's talk about where the supply curve comes from. 810 00:34:55,170 --> 00:34:56,920 We know where the demand curve comes from. 811 00:34:56,920 --> 00:34:58,837 It just simply comes from the marginal revenue 812 00:34:58,837 --> 00:35:00,350 product of capital. 813 00:35:00,350 --> 00:35:01,940 Where does supply curve comes from? 814 00:35:01,940 --> 00:35:08,000 The supply curve comes from what we call intertemporal choice. 815 00:35:11,870 --> 00:35:15,020 As I said, economists like putting fancy names on things. 816 00:35:15,020 --> 00:35:17,840 That helps us get paid more money. 817 00:35:17,840 --> 00:35:21,760 It just means choosing over time, intertemporal choice. 818 00:35:21,760 --> 00:35:24,400 Intertemporal choice is essentially about 819 00:35:24,400 --> 00:35:27,280 how do you decide how much to save. 820 00:35:27,280 --> 00:35:29,410 What's going to determine that is 821 00:35:29,410 --> 00:35:31,690 going to be your decision of how much you 822 00:35:31,690 --> 00:35:35,050 value money today versus valuing money tomorrow. 823 00:35:37,710 --> 00:35:40,980 So for ease, let's imagine I'm considering two periods, 824 00:35:40,980 --> 00:35:42,105 this year versus next year. 825 00:35:42,105 --> 00:35:44,563 When I talk about periods, I'm talking about days and years 826 00:35:44,563 --> 00:35:45,450 and whatever. 827 00:35:45,450 --> 00:35:46,380 It's the basic logic. 828 00:35:46,380 --> 00:35:47,680 It's about now versus the future. 829 00:35:47,680 --> 00:35:49,597 Whether I say days or years, it doesn't really 830 00:35:49,597 --> 00:35:50,305 matter right now. 831 00:35:50,305 --> 00:35:52,805 The point is I'm just talking about today versus the future. 832 00:35:52,805 --> 00:35:55,000 So let's talk about this year versus next year. 833 00:35:55,000 --> 00:35:57,020 And let's imagine prices aren't going to change. 834 00:35:57,020 --> 00:35:58,460 I'll come back to prices next lecture. 835 00:35:58,460 --> 00:36:00,590 But let's imagine the price of goods aren't going to go up. 836 00:36:00,590 --> 00:36:02,183 There's no inflation in this economy, 837 00:36:02,183 --> 00:36:03,350 which is roughly true today. 838 00:36:05,438 --> 00:36:07,480 And let's suppose I'm going to take next year off 839 00:36:07,480 --> 00:36:09,063 to care for my children. 840 00:36:09,063 --> 00:36:11,230 Lord knows why I'd want to do that when the youngest 841 00:36:11,230 --> 00:36:15,310 one's 19, but imagine they still need my care. 842 00:36:15,310 --> 00:36:18,280 So let's say I'll take next-- this example gets dated. 843 00:36:18,280 --> 00:36:22,580 Let's say I take next year off to care for my children. 844 00:36:22,580 --> 00:36:27,580 And let's say my income is $80,000 a year. 845 00:36:27,580 --> 00:36:29,193 Now, here is my-- 846 00:36:29,193 --> 00:36:30,985 but I'm going to take next year off unpaid. 847 00:36:33,670 --> 00:36:35,740 So I'm going to work this year for 80k. 848 00:36:35,740 --> 00:36:38,580 Next year I'm going to take off unpaid. 849 00:36:38,580 --> 00:36:40,320 So I have a couple of choices. 850 00:36:40,320 --> 00:36:44,770 I could work this year, earn my 80k, spend my 80k, 851 00:36:44,770 --> 00:36:48,150 and have nothing next year to live on. 852 00:36:48,150 --> 00:36:50,190 I could work this year and eat nothing 853 00:36:50,190 --> 00:36:52,770 and save all of the 80k to live on, 854 00:36:52,770 --> 00:36:54,640 or some combination in between. 855 00:36:54,640 --> 00:36:56,640 And we could illustrate-- but the key difference 856 00:36:56,640 --> 00:36:59,370 is every dollar that I don't consume 857 00:36:59,370 --> 00:37:03,738 this year that I save to consume next year earns interest. 858 00:37:03,738 --> 00:37:05,280 And that's where the trade-off comes. 859 00:37:05,280 --> 00:37:06,488 So let's look at figure 16-6. 860 00:37:09,650 --> 00:37:13,430 This is a familiar-looking optimization diagram. 861 00:37:13,430 --> 00:37:18,020 Now my optimization is not over pizza versus cookies, 862 00:37:18,020 --> 00:37:21,740 but my optimization is over consumption this period 863 00:37:21,740 --> 00:37:23,180 versus consumption next period. 864 00:37:23,180 --> 00:37:24,350 It's a bit mind-blowing. 865 00:37:24,350 --> 00:37:27,140 We're a little science-fictiony here, right? 866 00:37:27,140 --> 00:37:29,540 We're now not talking about choosing between two goods, 867 00:37:29,540 --> 00:37:33,160 like leisure and consumption or cookies and pizza. 868 00:37:33,160 --> 00:37:36,720 Now I'm talking about two time periods, consumption today 869 00:37:36,720 --> 00:37:38,280 versus consumption tomorrow. 870 00:37:38,280 --> 00:37:40,460 But that's the key thing about the tools 871 00:37:40,460 --> 00:37:41,725 we learn with consumer choice. 872 00:37:41,725 --> 00:37:43,225 Those tools are incredibly powerful. 873 00:37:43,225 --> 00:37:45,865 You just need to shove your problem into that framework. 874 00:37:45,865 --> 00:37:48,240 And we're going to shove our problem into this framework. 875 00:37:48,240 --> 00:37:52,240 The problem we're facing is how do I decide how much to save. 876 00:37:52,240 --> 00:37:56,710 Well, savings is a bad just like labor's a bad. 877 00:37:56,710 --> 00:37:59,590 What do we do when we have a bad to model? 878 00:37:59,590 --> 00:38:00,850 We don't model the bad. 879 00:38:00,850 --> 00:38:03,190 We model the complementary good. 880 00:38:03,190 --> 00:38:05,860 So our choice is, how much do I consume today? 881 00:38:08,760 --> 00:38:12,630 My choice is, how much do I consume today 882 00:38:12,630 --> 00:38:16,100 and how much am I going to save? 883 00:38:16,100 --> 00:38:20,263 Well, saving is a bad, but the other way to think about it 884 00:38:20,263 --> 00:38:21,680 is, how much am I going to consume 885 00:38:21,680 --> 00:38:24,350 today versus how much am I going to consume tomorrow? 886 00:38:24,350 --> 00:38:28,220 Then that's two goods and I can model them against each other. 887 00:38:28,220 --> 00:38:30,650 And that's what I do in figure 16-6. 888 00:38:30,650 --> 00:38:34,940 I model consumption today versus consumption next year. 889 00:38:34,940 --> 00:38:36,930 So here's my choices. 890 00:38:36,930 --> 00:38:40,170 As I said, if I consume everything today, 891 00:38:40,170 --> 00:38:42,470 I'm at the x-intercept at 80,000. 892 00:38:42,470 --> 00:38:45,900 I have 80,000 to consume today, nothing next year. 893 00:38:45,900 --> 00:38:49,750 If I consume everything next year, what do I get? 894 00:38:49,750 --> 00:38:52,900 Well, let's say the interest rate is 10%. 895 00:38:52,900 --> 00:38:56,450 What that means is then I'll have $88,000 next year. 896 00:38:56,450 --> 00:38:57,820 Why will I have more next year? 897 00:38:57,820 --> 00:39:00,850 Because by saving, I earn interest. 898 00:39:00,850 --> 00:39:04,090 By diverting my consumption to the future, I earn interest. 899 00:39:04,090 --> 00:39:07,730 At 10%, that means I would have $88,000 next year. 900 00:39:07,730 --> 00:39:11,530 So my budget constraint is the line with the slope minus 1 901 00:39:11,530 --> 00:39:16,670 plus I. My budget constraint is the line with the slope minus 1 902 00:39:16,670 --> 00:39:20,720 plus I. In other words, the price of consumption 903 00:39:20,720 --> 00:39:27,130 today in terms of consumption tomorrow is minus 1 plus I. 904 00:39:27,130 --> 00:39:28,220 OK, let me think about it. 905 00:39:28,220 --> 00:39:29,137 Let me say that again. 906 00:39:29,137 --> 00:39:30,930 It's really confusing. 907 00:39:30,930 --> 00:39:35,553 The price of consuming today instead of consuming tomorrow, 908 00:39:35,553 --> 00:39:37,470 assuming no inflation-- so prices are the same 909 00:39:37,470 --> 00:39:38,550 in the market-- 910 00:39:38,550 --> 00:39:41,940 is minus 1 plus I. Think about that. 911 00:39:41,940 --> 00:39:45,120 I find it useful to think back to the labor case for parallel. 912 00:39:45,120 --> 00:39:49,530 In the labor case, what did we say was the price of leisure? 913 00:39:49,530 --> 00:39:50,780 What was the price of leisure? 914 00:39:50,780 --> 00:39:52,322 Someone raise their hand and tell me. 915 00:39:52,322 --> 00:39:53,280 In the labor-- yeah? 916 00:39:53,280 --> 00:39:53,670 AUDIENCE: The wages. 917 00:39:53,670 --> 00:39:54,060 JONATHAN GRUBER: The wages. 918 00:39:54,060 --> 00:39:54,835 Why? 919 00:39:54,835 --> 00:39:57,540 AUDIENCE: Just because that's the opportunity cost of not-- 920 00:39:57,540 --> 00:39:57,870 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 921 00:39:57,870 --> 00:39:59,430 So by that same logic, can tell me 922 00:39:59,430 --> 00:40:02,610 why is the price of consuming today 1 plus I? 923 00:40:06,010 --> 00:40:07,810 AUDIENCE: Because if you choose to save, 924 00:40:07,810 --> 00:40:09,708 then we're effectively richer. 925 00:40:09,708 --> 00:40:10,750 JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly. 926 00:40:10,750 --> 00:40:13,000 The opportunity cost-- remember, we 927 00:40:13,000 --> 00:40:16,240 are an annoying discipline with a dismal science. 928 00:40:16,240 --> 00:40:19,103 We're telling you, hey, enjoy that cookie, but by the way, 929 00:40:19,103 --> 00:40:21,520 if you weren't eating that cookie, you could have 1 plus I 930 00:40:21,520 --> 00:40:23,890 cookies tomorrow. 931 00:40:23,890 --> 00:40:27,310 So just like we nag you for sitting around watching TV, 932 00:40:27,310 --> 00:40:29,800 we nag you for eating today by saying, 933 00:40:29,800 --> 00:40:33,940 hey, the more you consume today, the less you can have tomorrow. 934 00:40:33,940 --> 00:40:37,200 And in fact, that trade-off is that for every cookie 935 00:40:37,200 --> 00:40:41,220 you consume today, you forgo 1 plus I cookies tomorrow. 936 00:40:41,220 --> 00:40:42,630 So that's the budget constraint. 937 00:40:42,630 --> 00:40:45,390 The slope is the opportunity cost of consuming today 938 00:40:45,390 --> 00:40:47,250 in terms of tomorrow's consumption 939 00:40:47,250 --> 00:40:49,380 or next year's consumption, which 940 00:40:49,380 --> 00:40:52,645 is 1 plus I. That's the slope of the budget constraint, 941 00:40:52,645 --> 00:40:54,920 is the opportunity cost. 942 00:40:54,920 --> 00:40:58,272 And then, then we say, OK, well, that's the opportunity cost. 943 00:40:58,272 --> 00:40:59,480 That's the budget constraint. 944 00:40:59,480 --> 00:41:00,890 Well, how do I decide? 945 00:41:00,890 --> 00:41:03,110 Well, then we know how to make these decisions, which 946 00:41:03,110 --> 00:41:04,700 is go to utility function. 947 00:41:04,700 --> 00:41:07,070 You can write down the utility function, which 948 00:41:07,070 --> 00:41:08,795 is a function of C1 and C2. 949 00:41:12,520 --> 00:41:13,720 Now, what is C? 950 00:41:13,720 --> 00:41:16,450 C is all my pizza and cookies, but we're aggregating it up. 951 00:41:16,450 --> 00:41:18,970 Just like our utility function last time 952 00:41:18,970 --> 00:41:22,680 was a function of leisure and consumption-- 953 00:41:22,680 --> 00:41:25,347 we said consumption was the bundle of goods you eat 954 00:41:25,347 --> 00:41:26,430 and leisure is this thing. 955 00:41:26,430 --> 00:41:28,515 Now we're saying, OK, our utility function now 956 00:41:28,515 --> 00:41:30,210 is a function of this trade-off. 957 00:41:30,210 --> 00:41:31,853 Now, you might say, wait a second. 958 00:41:31,853 --> 00:41:33,520 How can both those be utility functions? 959 00:41:33,520 --> 00:41:35,937 And the answer is you have some meta-utility function that 960 00:41:35,937 --> 00:41:38,250 includes consumption today, tomorrow, leisure, pizza, 961 00:41:38,250 --> 00:41:40,170 cookies, et cetera. 962 00:41:40,170 --> 00:41:43,650 But we can think about this in sequential steps. 963 00:41:43,650 --> 00:41:47,160 First, we decide how we're going to split our income. 964 00:41:47,160 --> 00:41:49,710 Then we can decide what to spend it on each period. 965 00:41:49,710 --> 00:41:52,155 Then you can do a separate consumer maximization decision. 966 00:41:52,155 --> 00:41:53,655 But our first question is simply how 967 00:41:53,655 --> 00:41:54,972 am I going to split my income. 968 00:41:54,972 --> 00:41:56,430 Well, that's going to be a function 969 00:41:56,430 --> 00:42:01,430 of my taste for consumption in this period versus next period 970 00:42:01,430 --> 00:42:05,300 and the price the bank will pay me for delaying consumption 971 00:42:05,300 --> 00:42:07,850 till next period. 972 00:42:07,850 --> 00:42:09,590 Now, what happens? 973 00:42:09,590 --> 00:42:12,090 Questions about that? 974 00:42:12,090 --> 00:42:14,100 Now, what happens in the scenario 975 00:42:14,100 --> 00:42:16,580 when the interest rate goes up? 976 00:42:16,580 --> 00:42:18,900 What do you think happens if the interest rate goes up? 977 00:42:22,352 --> 00:42:22,852 Yeah? 978 00:42:22,852 --> 00:42:26,622 AUDIENCE: There's [INAUDIBLE]. 979 00:42:26,622 --> 00:42:27,580 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 980 00:42:27,580 --> 00:42:29,140 So what do you think you should-- 981 00:42:29,140 --> 00:42:31,810 what do you think will happen to your consumption pattern? 982 00:42:31,810 --> 00:42:32,350 Yeah? 983 00:42:32,350 --> 00:42:33,760 AUDIENCE: You should spend less today. 984 00:42:33,760 --> 00:42:34,540 JONATHAN GRUBER: Spend less today 985 00:42:34,540 --> 00:42:36,490 and save more because it's rewarded. 986 00:42:36,490 --> 00:42:39,650 And why is that not necessarily true? 987 00:42:39,650 --> 00:42:40,430 Yeah? 988 00:42:40,430 --> 00:42:42,350 AUDIENCE: Because you might only need a certain amount of money 989 00:42:42,350 --> 00:42:42,850 to live. 990 00:42:42,850 --> 00:42:44,835 So you don't have to save as much today 991 00:42:44,835 --> 00:42:45,710 because you'll make-- 992 00:42:45,710 --> 00:42:48,860 JONATHAN GRUBER: Because of what two effects? 993 00:42:48,860 --> 00:42:50,620 Income and substitution effects. 994 00:42:50,620 --> 00:42:53,790 You gave exactly the intuition that the substitution effect 995 00:42:53,790 --> 00:42:54,460 gives you. 996 00:42:54,460 --> 00:42:57,670 The substitution effect is exactly right. 997 00:42:57,670 --> 00:42:59,620 If the interest rate goes up, that's 998 00:42:59,620 --> 00:43:02,747 like the price of consumption today going up. 999 00:43:02,747 --> 00:43:04,330 And if the price of something goes up, 1000 00:43:04,330 --> 00:43:07,410 the substitution effect says you do less of it. 1001 00:43:07,410 --> 00:43:10,873 But if interest rate goes up, you're richer. 1002 00:43:10,873 --> 00:43:12,790 And if you're rich, you do more of everything, 1003 00:43:12,790 --> 00:43:14,500 including consuming today. 1004 00:43:14,500 --> 00:43:16,770 The income effect goes the other way. 1005 00:43:16,770 --> 00:43:17,598 It's like labor. 1006 00:43:17,598 --> 00:43:19,390 Once again, income and substitution effects 1007 00:43:19,390 --> 00:43:22,117 is why we bothered telling you so. 1008 00:43:22,117 --> 00:43:24,450 Because income and substitution effects, in these cases, 1009 00:43:24,450 --> 00:43:25,367 go against each other. 1010 00:43:25,367 --> 00:43:29,400 Let's look at figure 16-7, OK? 1011 00:43:29,400 --> 00:43:33,760 In figure 16-7, we start at point A. 1012 00:43:33,760 --> 00:43:38,510 Now imagine the interest rate doubles to 20%. 1013 00:43:38,510 --> 00:43:41,300 Now imagine the interest rate doubles. 1014 00:43:41,300 --> 00:43:44,270 As you said, that pivots the budget constraint upwards. 1015 00:43:44,270 --> 00:43:46,560 You could still consume only $80,000 this year, 1016 00:43:46,560 --> 00:43:50,950 but now for every dollar you save, you get $1.20 next year. 1017 00:43:50,950 --> 00:43:52,570 That has two effects on your decision. 1018 00:43:52,570 --> 00:43:56,020 The substitution effect, we get by drawing an imaginary budget 1019 00:43:56,020 --> 00:43:57,880 constraint-- that's the dash line-- 1020 00:43:57,880 --> 00:44:00,590 tangent to the original indifference curve 1021 00:44:00,590 --> 00:44:02,230 but at the new slope. 1022 00:44:02,230 --> 00:44:06,880 By definition, that means you consume less today. 1023 00:44:06,880 --> 00:44:08,823 You consume less today by definition. 1024 00:44:08,823 --> 00:44:10,240 If the price of something goes up, 1025 00:44:10,240 --> 00:44:12,820 the substitution effect always says you do less of it. 1026 00:44:12,820 --> 00:44:16,240 You consume less today, which means you'll save more. 1027 00:44:16,240 --> 00:44:22,120 Remember, savings is just income minus consumption 1028 00:44:22,120 --> 00:44:25,030 in period one. 1029 00:44:25,030 --> 00:44:30,280 So just as labor was 24 minus leisure-- 1030 00:44:30,280 --> 00:44:33,770 and so if we just solve for leisure, we could get labor. 1031 00:44:33,770 --> 00:44:38,150 Savings is just income minus consumption in period one. 1032 00:44:38,150 --> 00:44:40,790 So if we solve for consumption in period one, we get savings. 1033 00:44:44,500 --> 00:44:45,910 People see that? 1034 00:44:45,910 --> 00:44:48,910 So basically, the point here is the substitution effect 1035 00:44:48,910 --> 00:44:52,300 says, well, gee, the price of consumption in period one 1036 00:44:52,300 --> 00:44:53,800 just went up. 1037 00:44:53,800 --> 00:44:56,460 It's more costly in terms of future consumption. 1038 00:44:56,460 --> 00:44:58,960 I'm going to do less, but then my savings is going to go up. 1039 00:44:58,960 --> 00:45:01,090 Substitution effect says you save more. 1040 00:45:01,090 --> 00:45:03,290 But the income effect says, wait a second. 1041 00:45:03,290 --> 00:45:05,080 You're now richer. 1042 00:45:05,080 --> 00:45:07,030 Every dollar of your savings you are doing now 1043 00:45:07,030 --> 00:45:09,280 yields twice as much in interest. 1044 00:45:09,280 --> 00:45:13,210 If you're richer, you'll consume more of everything, including 1045 00:45:13,210 --> 00:45:14,950 period one consumption. 1046 00:45:14,950 --> 00:45:18,048 So the income effect takes you back the other way. 1047 00:45:18,048 --> 00:45:20,090 Now, whether the income effect dominates are not, 1048 00:45:20,090 --> 00:45:20,810 we don't know. 1049 00:45:20,810 --> 00:45:22,227 In this case, it doesn't dominate. 1050 00:45:22,227 --> 00:45:24,200 In this case, you still, on net, end up 1051 00:45:24,200 --> 00:45:27,840 consuming less in period one and saving more. 1052 00:45:27,840 --> 00:45:30,637 But we don't know what's going to dominate. 1053 00:45:30,637 --> 00:45:32,720 And in fact, the evidence here is incredibly weak. 1054 00:45:32,720 --> 00:45:33,940 I won't spend a long time on the evidence 1055 00:45:33,940 --> 00:45:35,830 because it's not nearly as interesting and strong as labor 1056 00:45:35,830 --> 00:45:36,580 supply. 1057 00:45:36,580 --> 00:45:39,108 The evidence is incredibly weak even about the sign. 1058 00:45:39,108 --> 00:45:41,400 And let's come to the intuition that was given for why. 1059 00:45:41,400 --> 00:45:44,800 Well, think about how people make savings decisions. 1060 00:45:44,800 --> 00:45:47,380 Lots of people have savings goals. 1061 00:45:47,380 --> 00:45:49,720 I want to have x by the time I retire. 1062 00:45:49,720 --> 00:45:52,342 Typical way if you ask people about their savings-- 1063 00:45:52,342 --> 00:45:53,800 if you ask them, they typically say 1064 00:45:53,800 --> 00:45:55,800 I want to make sure I have x in the bank in case 1065 00:45:55,800 --> 00:45:56,650 I'm in an accident. 1066 00:45:56,650 --> 00:45:59,080 I want to make sure I have y by the time I retire. 1067 00:45:59,080 --> 00:46:01,930 Well, in those models, if the interest rate goes up, 1068 00:46:01,930 --> 00:46:04,335 savings rates go down. 1069 00:46:04,335 --> 00:46:06,710 Because after all, to hit a target with a higher interest 1070 00:46:06,710 --> 00:46:08,510 rate, I can save less. 1071 00:46:08,510 --> 00:46:10,045 So it's actually not that surprising 1072 00:46:10,045 --> 00:46:11,420 that you'd have a higher interest 1073 00:46:11,420 --> 00:46:13,280 rate leading to less savings. 1074 00:46:13,280 --> 00:46:15,170 It's kind of intuitive, actually. 1075 00:46:15,170 --> 00:46:17,600 If people have savings targets, a higher interest rate 1076 00:46:17,600 --> 00:46:18,710 would lead to less savings because they can get 1077 00:46:18,710 --> 00:46:20,520 to their target more easily. 1078 00:46:20,520 --> 00:46:22,040 So actually, we don't even know which way this goes. 1079 00:46:22,040 --> 00:46:24,123 It's, I think, one of the great unsolved mysteries 1080 00:46:24,123 --> 00:46:27,120 in economics empirically, is, once again, 1081 00:46:27,120 --> 00:46:29,000 we typically assume-- 1082 00:46:29,000 --> 00:46:30,470 and with a gun to my head, I would 1083 00:46:30,470 --> 00:46:32,810 say it's probably true that higher interest rates leads 1084 00:46:32,810 --> 00:46:34,660 to more savings. 1085 00:46:34,660 --> 00:46:38,930 But the evidence on which that rests is pretty weak. 1086 00:46:38,930 --> 00:46:41,420 And the key point for you is to understand it's uncertain 1087 00:46:41,420 --> 00:46:43,480 and it depends on whether income and substitution 1088 00:46:43,480 --> 00:46:46,540 effects dominate. 1089 00:46:46,540 --> 00:46:49,030 Questions about that? 1090 00:46:49,030 --> 00:46:49,640 OK. 1091 00:46:49,640 --> 00:46:51,740 So now let's step back and put it all together 1092 00:46:51,740 --> 00:46:55,873 and think about you making your decision about life. 1093 00:46:55,873 --> 00:46:57,290 You can think about your decisions 1094 00:46:57,290 --> 00:47:02,040 about your life in three steps. 1095 00:47:02,040 --> 00:47:06,820 Step one is you decide how hard to work. 1096 00:47:06,820 --> 00:47:09,760 Step one is you decide, how much money do I want to make? 1097 00:47:09,760 --> 00:47:12,010 Well, that's about maximizing utility 1098 00:47:12,010 --> 00:47:15,530 over consumption and leisure. 1099 00:47:15,530 --> 00:47:18,200 Step two is, having decided how much you're going to make-- 1100 00:47:18,200 --> 00:47:20,713 and that yields your labor. 1101 00:47:20,713 --> 00:47:22,880 Step two is, deciding how much you're going to make, 1102 00:47:22,880 --> 00:47:25,693 you decide, well, how do I want to spread that over time? 1103 00:47:25,693 --> 00:47:27,860 How much do I want to consume today versus tomorrow? 1104 00:47:27,860 --> 00:47:29,660 Well, that's about intertemporal choice. 1105 00:47:29,660 --> 00:47:32,480 That's about deciding on C1 versus C2, 1106 00:47:32,480 --> 00:47:35,980 and that's going to yield your savings. 1107 00:47:35,980 --> 00:47:38,260 Step three is, now that I know how much I'm 1108 00:47:38,260 --> 00:47:40,070 going to consume each period, now 1109 00:47:40,070 --> 00:47:42,280 I want to maximize utility across all my goods 1110 00:47:42,280 --> 00:47:44,890 I might want to consume-- x2, across all 1111 00:47:44,890 --> 00:47:46,870 the goods I want to consume. 1112 00:47:46,870 --> 00:47:50,240 That was our original cookies and pizza example. 1113 00:47:50,240 --> 00:47:52,510 So you could think of it as a hierarchical set 1114 00:47:52,510 --> 00:47:55,240 of consumer optimization problems 1115 00:47:55,240 --> 00:47:57,100 that you're going to solve. 1116 00:47:57,100 --> 00:47:59,230 Now, you might say, well, gee, Jon, 1117 00:47:59,230 --> 00:48:02,290 that's sort of confusing because, in fact, the interest 1118 00:48:02,290 --> 00:48:04,180 rate and how much am I saving could determine 1119 00:48:04,180 --> 00:48:06,160 how hard I work, right? 1120 00:48:06,160 --> 00:48:07,933 Let's say the interest rate goes way up 1121 00:48:07,933 --> 00:48:09,100 and I have a savings target. 1122 00:48:09,100 --> 00:48:11,320 I have to work less hard to hit that savings target. 1123 00:48:11,320 --> 00:48:12,830 And I'd say to you, good for you. 1124 00:48:12,830 --> 00:48:14,488 Take more advanced economics. 1125 00:48:14,488 --> 00:48:16,030 More advanced economics, we recognize 1126 00:48:16,030 --> 00:48:18,322 this is one integrated whole and we allow these systems 1127 00:48:18,322 --> 00:48:20,080 to affect each other. 1128 00:48:20,080 --> 00:48:24,490 But for here, just think of them as separatable steps, 1129 00:48:24,490 --> 00:48:25,630 independent steps. 1130 00:48:25,630 --> 00:48:27,280 But in practice, I hope you can see 1131 00:48:27,280 --> 00:48:29,910 the steps will be integrated and they'll affect each other. 1132 00:48:29,910 --> 00:48:30,410 Think of it. 1133 00:48:30,410 --> 00:48:33,190 If the price of a good you really want to buy 1134 00:48:33,190 --> 00:48:36,310 goes up a lot, not only will you buy less of that good; 1135 00:48:36,310 --> 00:48:38,505 you might save more to buy it and work harder. 1136 00:48:38,505 --> 00:48:40,630 So you can imagine how these things are integrated. 1137 00:48:40,630 --> 00:48:43,340 But for now, we'll keep them separable, OK? 1138 00:48:43,340 --> 00:48:45,210 Questions about that? 1139 00:48:45,210 --> 00:48:45,710 OK. 1140 00:48:45,710 --> 00:48:47,293 Next time, we're to come back and talk 1141 00:48:47,293 --> 00:48:49,940 about all the interesting stuff in capital markets 1142 00:48:49,940 --> 00:48:52,910 and how we make decisions about how much to save 1143 00:48:52,910 --> 00:48:54,880 and things like that.