1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:04,810 [SQUEAKING] [RUSTLING] [CLICKING] 2 00:00:11,745 --> 00:00:13,120 JONATHAN GRUBER: All right, let's 3 00:00:13,120 --> 00:00:16,570 get started today with our lecture on factor markets. 4 00:00:20,230 --> 00:00:24,010 So when we talked about producer theory, 5 00:00:24,010 --> 00:00:27,670 we talked about input prices, that firms 6 00:00:27,670 --> 00:00:30,432 had prices for their wages and their capital. 7 00:00:30,432 --> 00:00:32,140 And we just sort of posed those as given. 8 00:00:32,140 --> 00:00:33,932 I just sort of gave you values for the wage 9 00:00:33,932 --> 00:00:35,430 and the renter rate of capital. 10 00:00:35,430 --> 00:00:38,360 But we never really talked about where those prices come from. 11 00:00:38,360 --> 00:00:40,360 Given that they may be the most important prices 12 00:00:40,360 --> 00:00:42,400 in our whole economy, it's probably worth 13 00:00:42,400 --> 00:00:44,680 spending a little time on talking about where 14 00:00:44,680 --> 00:00:46,780 do w and r actually come from. 15 00:00:46,780 --> 00:00:49,030 And that's we'll do for the next three lectures, 16 00:00:49,030 --> 00:00:52,270 is talk about factor markets, talk about the markets 17 00:00:52,270 --> 00:00:56,860 that give us the price of labor and capital. 18 00:00:56,860 --> 00:00:59,440 We're going to start by talking about factor 19 00:00:59,440 --> 00:01:04,065 demand, the general demand for labor and capital. 20 00:01:04,065 --> 00:01:06,190 And then we'll move on to talk about factor supply, 21 00:01:06,190 --> 00:01:07,852 where does supply come from. 22 00:01:07,852 --> 00:01:09,310 We'll then develop the equilibrium, 23 00:01:09,310 --> 00:01:12,790 and that will tell us where wages and the interest rate 24 00:01:12,790 --> 00:01:13,892 come from. 25 00:01:13,892 --> 00:01:15,850 So that's sort of the map of where we're going, 26 00:01:15,850 --> 00:01:17,980 is we're basically going to develop 27 00:01:17,980 --> 00:01:21,490 the markets that give us the wage rate and the interest 28 00:01:21,490 --> 00:01:22,490 rate. 29 00:01:22,490 --> 00:01:29,060 So let's start with factor demand, factor demand. 30 00:01:29,060 --> 00:01:32,450 And let's start, and we're going to start 31 00:01:32,450 --> 00:01:33,728 with the cleanest case. 32 00:01:33,728 --> 00:01:36,020 We're going to assume that factor markets are perfectly 33 00:01:36,020 --> 00:01:37,350 competitive. 34 00:01:37,350 --> 00:01:39,590 So unless I say otherwise, we're assuming 35 00:01:39,590 --> 00:01:41,990 the market for workers, or the market 36 00:01:41,990 --> 00:01:45,450 for machines, or capital, is perfectly competitive. 37 00:01:45,450 --> 00:01:48,510 OK, we'll come back and bend that a little bit later. 38 00:01:48,510 --> 00:01:51,770 So what that means is that there's basically many sellers 39 00:01:51,770 --> 00:01:53,390 and buyers, OK? 40 00:01:53,390 --> 00:01:56,360 So any worker is basically competing 41 00:01:56,360 --> 00:01:59,210 with lots of workers for jobs. 42 00:01:59,210 --> 00:02:01,160 Any firm is competing with lots of firms 43 00:02:01,160 --> 00:02:04,913 to hire the workers, OK? 44 00:02:04,913 --> 00:02:05,830 And we're also going-- 45 00:02:05,830 --> 00:02:08,610 we're going to assume a perfectly competitive input 46 00:02:08,610 --> 00:02:12,310 market, that is lots of firms and workers 47 00:02:12,310 --> 00:02:14,135 competing to match with each other. 48 00:02:14,135 --> 00:02:16,510 We're also going to assume a perfectly competitive output 49 00:02:16,510 --> 00:02:20,740 market, that is, we're going to examine this for the case 50 00:02:20,740 --> 00:02:23,970 not of a monopoly firm but of a perfectly competitive firm. 51 00:02:23,970 --> 00:02:26,470 So just think of this, you have a perfectly competitive firm 52 00:02:26,470 --> 00:02:30,910 competing with lots of other firms to hire workers, OK? 53 00:02:30,910 --> 00:02:34,180 So let's start by talking about short run labor 54 00:02:34,180 --> 00:02:37,950 demand in this context. 55 00:02:37,950 --> 00:02:40,210 Let's talk about short run labor demand. 56 00:02:40,210 --> 00:02:43,260 Now, in the short run, capital is fixed. 57 00:02:43,260 --> 00:02:47,320 So our decision is just, do we add another worker or not, 58 00:02:47,320 --> 00:02:48,750 or another hour of labor or not. 59 00:02:48,750 --> 00:02:50,850 Like I said, the units don't really matter here, 60 00:02:50,850 --> 00:02:52,620 but let's take in terms of workers. 61 00:02:52,620 --> 00:02:56,500 Do we add another worker or not? 62 00:02:56,500 --> 00:02:58,843 Well, as with everything else in this course, 63 00:02:58,843 --> 00:03:01,510 we want to consider the marginal benefits and the marginal costs 64 00:03:01,510 --> 00:03:03,580 of that decision. 65 00:03:03,580 --> 00:03:09,230 The marginal benefit of an extra worker 66 00:03:09,230 --> 00:03:13,580 is that one extra unit of labor raises productivity 67 00:03:13,580 --> 00:03:16,760 by the marginal product of labor, OK? 68 00:03:16,760 --> 00:03:19,910 One more unit of labor raises our output 69 00:03:19,910 --> 00:03:24,200 by the marginal product of labor, OK? 70 00:03:24,200 --> 00:03:26,660 But that's not the only part of the benefit, 71 00:03:26,660 --> 00:03:28,900 because we don't actually care as a firm about units 72 00:03:28,900 --> 00:03:29,720 of output. 73 00:03:29,720 --> 00:03:32,700 We care about revenues. 74 00:03:32,700 --> 00:03:37,320 So the benefit of a worker is not just the how many units 75 00:03:37,320 --> 00:03:41,580 it produces, but the value of those units. 76 00:03:41,580 --> 00:03:44,700 And what is the value of the next unit produced? 77 00:03:44,700 --> 00:03:47,760 It's the marginal revenue. 78 00:03:47,760 --> 00:03:50,270 So the value of the next unit of labor 79 00:03:50,270 --> 00:03:55,635 is what we call the marginal revenue product, MRP sub 80 00:03:55,635 --> 00:03:57,530 L. The marginal revenue product is 81 00:03:57,530 --> 00:04:02,340 the marginal product of labor times marginal revenue. 82 00:04:02,340 --> 00:04:05,430 That's the benefit of another unit of labor. 83 00:04:05,430 --> 00:04:09,340 It's not just what they make, but what it's worth. 84 00:04:09,340 --> 00:04:14,860 It's not just what they make, but what it's worth, OK? 85 00:04:14,860 --> 00:04:16,833 So that's the marginal benefit. 86 00:04:16,833 --> 00:04:18,250 The value of another unit of labor 87 00:04:18,250 --> 00:04:22,130 is it makes marginal revenue product amount more stuff, 88 00:04:22,130 --> 00:04:25,233 and you sell that at the marginal revenue. 89 00:04:25,233 --> 00:04:26,400 That's the marginal benefit. 90 00:04:26,400 --> 00:04:29,035 What's the marginal cost of another unit of labor? 91 00:04:29,035 --> 00:04:31,410 So this is the marginal benefit of another unit of labor. 92 00:04:31,410 --> 00:04:33,610 What's the marginal cost? 93 00:04:33,610 --> 00:04:36,500 Well, the marginal cost of labor is just the wage. 94 00:04:36,500 --> 00:04:39,730 So we simply set this equal to the wage. 95 00:04:39,730 --> 00:04:41,920 We set the marginal revenue product of labor 96 00:04:41,920 --> 00:04:45,670 equal to the wage, and that gives us our optimization 97 00:04:45,670 --> 00:04:48,930 condition for the optimal amount of labor 98 00:04:48,930 --> 00:04:51,040 the firms want to demand-- 99 00:04:51,040 --> 00:04:53,980 is to set the marginal revenue product of labor 100 00:04:53,980 --> 00:04:54,880 equal to the wage. 101 00:04:57,660 --> 00:04:59,850 Marginal benefits of hiring another unit of labor 102 00:04:59,850 --> 00:05:03,010 equals the marginal cost of hiring of the unit of labor. 103 00:05:03,010 --> 00:05:05,920 Now to go further, remember, I said 104 00:05:05,920 --> 00:05:08,273 this is a perfectly competitive output market. 105 00:05:08,273 --> 00:05:10,690 So what is the marginal revenue in a perfectly competitive 106 00:05:10,690 --> 00:05:12,510 output market? 107 00:05:12,510 --> 00:05:14,910 What's the marginal revenue of a firm producing-- yeah. 108 00:05:14,910 --> 00:05:15,600 Price. 109 00:05:15,600 --> 00:05:18,540 So I can write this more to say that I 110 00:05:18,540 --> 00:05:22,140 want to set the marginal product of labor times the price equal 111 00:05:22,140 --> 00:05:26,380 to the wage, OK? 112 00:05:26,380 --> 00:05:28,450 So basically, what we're saying here-- 113 00:05:28,450 --> 00:05:32,800 think about it-- is hire workers until the cost of the next unit 114 00:05:32,800 --> 00:05:36,430 of labor is the same as what that unit will actually 115 00:05:36,430 --> 00:05:38,700 produce for you, OK? 116 00:05:38,700 --> 00:05:41,190 The next unit of labor costs you w. 117 00:05:41,190 --> 00:05:43,680 It produces for you MPL times p. 118 00:05:43,680 --> 00:05:45,990 So you want to hire workers until that condition is 119 00:05:45,990 --> 00:05:47,820 met, OK? 120 00:05:47,820 --> 00:05:53,640 So think about that, and figure 15-1 sort of shows this, OK? 121 00:05:53,640 --> 00:05:57,410 We have a supply of labor. 122 00:05:57,410 --> 00:05:59,790 In 15-1, that's horizontal, because we're 123 00:05:59,790 --> 00:06:03,462 assuming competitive market for workers, OK? 124 00:06:03,462 --> 00:06:04,920 We're assuming a competitive market 125 00:06:04,920 --> 00:06:08,200 for workers, that is a perfectly competitive market. 126 00:06:08,200 --> 00:06:11,550 So if I try to pay workers one penny more than other firms, 127 00:06:11,550 --> 00:06:14,100 every worker in the world will want to work for me. 128 00:06:14,100 --> 00:06:16,920 If I pay workers one penny less than other firms, 129 00:06:16,920 --> 00:06:19,140 no workers will want to work for me. 130 00:06:19,140 --> 00:06:21,270 That's what a perfectly competitive labor market 131 00:06:21,270 --> 00:06:25,590 means, that literally, I am a price taker in the input 132 00:06:25,590 --> 00:06:26,820 market. 133 00:06:26,820 --> 00:06:29,510 I don't get to set the wage, OK? 134 00:06:29,510 --> 00:06:31,740 I don't get to set the wage. 135 00:06:31,740 --> 00:06:35,890 The wage is given to me by the labor market. 136 00:06:35,890 --> 00:06:38,222 So just like a perfectly competitive firm 137 00:06:38,222 --> 00:06:40,180 doesn't get to set the price of their product-- 138 00:06:40,180 --> 00:06:42,660 it's given to them by the competitive market. 139 00:06:42,660 --> 00:06:44,970 A perfectly competitive firm in the input market 140 00:06:44,970 --> 00:06:47,220 doesn't get to set the wage they pay. 141 00:06:47,220 --> 00:06:49,230 It's given them through the kind of process 142 00:06:49,230 --> 00:06:53,580 that delivered us our prices on the output side, OK? 143 00:06:53,580 --> 00:06:56,790 So we get a horizontal labor supply curve. 144 00:06:56,790 --> 00:07:00,390 And then we have this downward sloping labor demand curve. 145 00:07:00,390 --> 00:07:01,670 Why is it downward sloping? 146 00:07:01,670 --> 00:07:03,240 Someone raise their hand and tell me. 147 00:07:03,240 --> 00:07:05,970 Why is the labor demand curve downward sloping? 148 00:07:08,610 --> 00:07:09,110 Yeah. 149 00:07:09,110 --> 00:07:11,470 AUDIENCE: Marginal product of labor is diminishing. 150 00:07:11,470 --> 00:07:12,512 JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly. 151 00:07:12,512 --> 00:07:14,740 The diminishing marginal product of labor 152 00:07:14,740 --> 00:07:17,380 means you have a downward sloping 153 00:07:17,380 --> 00:07:19,390 marginal benefit of labor. 154 00:07:19,390 --> 00:07:21,560 Each additional-- remember, holding capital fixed 155 00:07:21,560 --> 00:07:23,380 is only one shovel. 156 00:07:23,380 --> 00:07:25,990 So each additional worker add less and less 157 00:07:25,990 --> 00:07:28,630 to digging that hole, OK? 158 00:07:28,630 --> 00:07:30,100 So marginal product is diminishing. 159 00:07:30,100 --> 00:07:32,830 Since p is a constant, that doesn't really 160 00:07:32,830 --> 00:07:33,692 affect the slope. 161 00:07:33,692 --> 00:07:34,900 I mean, it affects the slope. 162 00:07:34,900 --> 00:07:37,030 It doesn't really affect the sign. 163 00:07:37,030 --> 00:07:38,235 Doesn't affect the sign. 164 00:07:38,235 --> 00:07:40,485 It's diminishing because the marginal product of labor 165 00:07:40,485 --> 00:07:41,780 is diminishing. 166 00:07:41,780 --> 00:07:46,530 So the equilibrium is where they intersect. 167 00:07:46,530 --> 00:07:49,610 So the bottom line-- this is complicated and new-- 168 00:07:49,610 --> 00:07:52,760 the bottom line intuition is to think about, 169 00:07:52,760 --> 00:07:56,840 as I decide whether to hire one more hour of work-- 170 00:07:56,840 --> 00:07:57,980 you've got a firm. 171 00:07:57,980 --> 00:07:59,730 You've got to decide, do I want the worker 172 00:07:59,730 --> 00:08:00,790 to work one more hour? 173 00:08:00,790 --> 00:08:02,167 You do the tradeoff of, what am I 174 00:08:02,167 --> 00:08:04,250 going to pay them for an hour versus what are they 175 00:08:04,250 --> 00:08:05,840 going to get me for an hour. 176 00:08:05,840 --> 00:08:08,090 What they're going to get me is their marginal product 177 00:08:08,090 --> 00:08:11,510 times the price, OK? 178 00:08:11,510 --> 00:08:13,920 Now, that-- 179 00:08:13,920 --> 00:08:16,580 So in other words, the wage is not just the marginal product. 180 00:08:16,580 --> 00:08:19,280 It's imagining if two workers were equally productive. 181 00:08:19,280 --> 00:08:22,950 With one more hour of work, they each make three more units. 182 00:08:22,950 --> 00:08:27,330 But let's say, in one case, a unit is a computer chip, OK? 183 00:08:27,330 --> 00:08:31,700 In another case, a unit is a potato chip. 184 00:08:31,700 --> 00:08:34,086 We clearly would not want to pay the same wage to someone 185 00:08:34,086 --> 00:08:36,669 who produces three more computer chips to someone who produces 186 00:08:36,669 --> 00:08:39,080 three more potato chips. 187 00:08:39,080 --> 00:08:40,790 We'd want to pay a lot more to the person 188 00:08:40,790 --> 00:08:41,873 to do more computer chips. 189 00:08:41,873 --> 00:08:42,530 Why? 190 00:08:42,530 --> 00:08:44,070 Not because computers are inherently valuable. 191 00:08:44,070 --> 00:08:45,945 In fact, potato chips are much more delicious 192 00:08:45,945 --> 00:08:47,480 than computer chips. 193 00:08:47,480 --> 00:08:50,460 Because they sell for a higher price. 194 00:08:50,460 --> 00:08:52,490 So therefore, you'd want to pay more 195 00:08:52,490 --> 00:08:56,270 to the worker who produces more units of a more valuable good. 196 00:08:56,270 --> 00:09:01,145 So let's think about a sports example, OK? 197 00:09:01,145 --> 00:09:03,020 And I realize we're all about baseball today, 198 00:09:03,020 --> 00:09:03,800 as we should be. 199 00:09:03,800 --> 00:09:04,880 Go, Red Sox. 200 00:09:04,880 --> 00:09:09,410 But let's focus on basketball for a minute, OK? 201 00:09:09,410 --> 00:09:12,500 Now, imagine you're a owner of a team in the NBA, the National 202 00:09:12,500 --> 00:09:14,180 Basketball Association, and you're 203 00:09:14,180 --> 00:09:18,070 trying to decide how much you pay one of your players. 204 00:09:18,070 --> 00:09:22,090 So basically, in that case, your goal is to-- 205 00:09:22,090 --> 00:09:23,800 your goal is wins. 206 00:09:23,800 --> 00:09:24,593 That's the goal. 207 00:09:24,593 --> 00:09:27,010 That's the profit you're trying to maximize, is your wins. 208 00:09:27,010 --> 00:09:29,110 Let's say you're probably trying to maximize 209 00:09:29,110 --> 00:09:31,300 your revenues from ads and stuff, 210 00:09:31,300 --> 00:09:33,125 but assume that's proportional to wins. 211 00:09:33,125 --> 00:09:34,750 OK, assume that basically, the more you 212 00:09:34,750 --> 00:09:36,090 win, the more money you make. 213 00:09:36,090 --> 00:09:39,400 So let's say the thing you're trying to maximize is wins, OK? 214 00:09:39,400 --> 00:09:41,680 So your labor demand, the marginal product 215 00:09:41,680 --> 00:09:45,400 you care about, is the contribution of the next player 216 00:09:45,400 --> 00:09:46,985 to your win total. 217 00:09:46,985 --> 00:09:48,110 That's what you care about. 218 00:09:48,110 --> 00:09:51,440 The marginal product of labor is how much does that next player 219 00:09:51,440 --> 00:09:54,140 add to my win total, OK? 220 00:09:54,140 --> 00:09:57,248 So for example, LeBron James, the best player in basketball, 221 00:09:57,248 --> 00:09:58,790 arguably the best player in history-- 222 00:09:58,790 --> 00:10:01,290 we could have that-- we could have the LeBron versus Michael 223 00:10:01,290 --> 00:10:02,690 debate some other time, OK? 224 00:10:02,690 --> 00:10:07,100 LeBron James makes $31 million, and that's 225 00:10:07,100 --> 00:10:10,070 because his marginal product is enormous. 226 00:10:10,070 --> 00:10:13,520 He adds a huge amount of wins to any team, OK? 227 00:10:13,520 --> 00:10:14,395 We'll see with the-- 228 00:10:14,395 --> 00:10:15,770 we'll run the experiment to watch 229 00:10:15,770 --> 00:10:18,190 how the Cleveland Cavaliers tank this year once LeBron 230 00:10:18,190 --> 00:10:20,730 has left, OK? 231 00:10:20,730 --> 00:10:22,860 Now, other players don't make as much. 232 00:10:22,860 --> 00:10:25,530 Let's compare LeBron James to Nate Robinson. 233 00:10:25,530 --> 00:10:27,570 You guys might not know Nate Robinson is. 234 00:10:27,570 --> 00:10:30,420 He's one of the shortest players in the history of the NBA 235 00:10:30,420 --> 00:10:33,960 at a paltry 5'9", which sounds pretty tall to you and I, 236 00:10:33,960 --> 00:10:36,540 but it's tiny for the NBA. 237 00:10:36,540 --> 00:10:37,830 He was a very exciting player. 238 00:10:37,830 --> 00:10:39,030 It's kind of fun to watch this little guy 239 00:10:39,030 --> 00:10:39,988 run among these giants. 240 00:10:42,690 --> 00:10:44,218 But he was just OK. 241 00:10:44,218 --> 00:10:45,260 He wasn't a great player. 242 00:10:45,260 --> 00:10:46,135 He was a fine player. 243 00:10:46,135 --> 00:10:50,160 He made about $2 million a year by the end of his career. 244 00:10:50,160 --> 00:10:52,848 So basically, you have LeBron making 31 million 245 00:10:52,848 --> 00:10:54,390 and Nate Robinson making two million, 246 00:10:54,390 --> 00:10:56,598 and that's sort of related to their marginal product. 247 00:10:56,598 --> 00:10:58,440 So LeBron adds a lot more to your wins. 248 00:10:58,440 --> 00:11:00,362 Now, what happened is Nate Robinson 249 00:11:00,362 --> 00:11:01,820 quit basketball in the US, and went 250 00:11:01,820 --> 00:11:03,697 to play basketball in Israel. 251 00:11:03,697 --> 00:11:05,030 In Israel, they love basketball. 252 00:11:05,030 --> 00:11:05,540 They have a league. 253 00:11:05,540 --> 00:11:07,280 And he went to Israel, and he was dominant. 254 00:11:07,280 --> 00:11:09,530 He was the best player in Israel, because they don't-- 255 00:11:09,530 --> 00:11:11,780 it's not as good as the US, OK? 256 00:11:11,780 --> 00:11:14,348 So his marginal product went way up. 257 00:11:14,348 --> 00:11:15,890 Nate Robinson went from being someone 258 00:11:15,890 --> 00:11:18,140 that had a small marginal product to maybe the highest 259 00:11:18,140 --> 00:11:22,020 marginal product in the league, and his wage went down 260 00:11:22,020 --> 00:11:24,390 from two million to 500,000. 261 00:11:24,390 --> 00:11:26,890 So this is a situation where someone's marginal product went 262 00:11:26,890 --> 00:11:29,680 way up and their wage went down. 263 00:11:29,680 --> 00:11:31,460 Why? 264 00:11:31,460 --> 00:11:32,183 Yeah. 265 00:11:32,183 --> 00:11:34,100 AUDIENCE: Because people aren't paying as much 266 00:11:34,100 --> 00:11:34,920 to watch basketball. 267 00:11:34,920 --> 00:11:37,462 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right, because the marginal product went up, 268 00:11:37,462 --> 00:11:39,880 but the price went way down, OK? 269 00:11:39,880 --> 00:11:41,510 And what we care about is the wage 270 00:11:41,510 --> 00:11:43,750 equals to marginal product times the price. 271 00:11:43,750 --> 00:11:47,260 So you have a situation where a player got better but got paid 272 00:11:47,260 --> 00:11:48,782 less because they got better. 273 00:11:48,782 --> 00:11:51,240 He moved from making computer chips to making potato chips, 274 00:11:51,240 --> 00:11:51,982 OK? 275 00:11:51,982 --> 00:11:53,440 He moved from a market where he was 276 00:11:53,440 --> 00:11:55,440 earning a valuable commodity to one where he was 277 00:11:55,440 --> 00:11:58,130 earning one that was much less. 278 00:11:58,130 --> 00:12:01,228 So basically, it's a situation-- that example 279 00:12:01,228 --> 00:12:02,770 shows why you have to care about both 280 00:12:02,770 --> 00:12:06,250 the quantity of the additional worker and the value of what 281 00:12:06,250 --> 00:12:08,530 they're producing, OK? 282 00:12:08,530 --> 00:12:11,070 Any questions about that? 283 00:12:11,070 --> 00:12:11,715 Yeah. 284 00:12:11,715 --> 00:12:14,417 AUDIENCE: When we talk about perfectly competitive input 285 00:12:14,417 --> 00:12:18,228 market, are we saying that like all of the workers-- 286 00:12:18,228 --> 00:12:20,520 like a single hour of work regardless of who you get it 287 00:12:20,520 --> 00:12:22,100 from is equal, right? 288 00:12:22,100 --> 00:12:23,100 JONATHAN GRUBER: No, no. 289 00:12:23,100 --> 00:12:24,660 A single hour of work is paid equally. 290 00:12:24,660 --> 00:12:25,290 It's not equal. 291 00:12:25,290 --> 00:12:26,110 Marginal product varies. 292 00:12:26,110 --> 00:12:27,400 We're talking about the market. 293 00:12:27,400 --> 00:12:28,650 Let's think about a perfectly competitive-- 294 00:12:28,650 --> 00:12:29,820 I probably went too fast with this. 295 00:12:29,820 --> 00:12:31,950 Let's say a perfectly competitive output market 296 00:12:31,950 --> 00:12:36,028 is where the firms sell the goods into a market 297 00:12:36,028 --> 00:12:37,570 where people have perfect information 298 00:12:37,570 --> 00:12:39,510 and can shop across all firms easily. 299 00:12:39,510 --> 00:12:41,010 A perfectly competitive input market 300 00:12:41,010 --> 00:12:44,040 is where firms hire workers in a situation workers 301 00:12:44,040 --> 00:12:46,470 have perfect information and compare across all firms 302 00:12:46,470 --> 00:12:47,610 equally. 303 00:12:47,610 --> 00:12:50,387 So basically, the point is, think about a perfectly 304 00:12:50,387 --> 00:12:51,470 competitive output market. 305 00:12:51,470 --> 00:12:53,860 People are in a market where lots of people are shopping, 306 00:12:53,860 --> 00:12:55,330 and all the options are in front of them. 307 00:12:55,330 --> 00:12:57,747 A perfectly competitive labor market where you as a worker 308 00:12:57,747 --> 00:12:59,490 have lots of firms you can work for, 309 00:12:59,490 --> 00:13:01,443 and they're all clearly in front of you, 310 00:13:01,443 --> 00:13:03,360 and they all offer a wage, and you can see it. 311 00:13:03,360 --> 00:13:04,492 AUDIENCE: OK, but we're not saying 312 00:13:04,492 --> 00:13:06,725 that the firms have perfect information across all 313 00:13:06,725 --> 00:13:08,965 the laborers, and [INAUDIBLE]. 314 00:13:08,965 --> 00:13:10,433 Are we saying if we have the-- 315 00:13:10,433 --> 00:13:11,850 JONATHAN GRUBER: What we're saying 316 00:13:11,850 --> 00:13:13,680 is-- we're not saying the firms have perfect information 317 00:13:13,680 --> 00:13:14,970 about the laborers. 318 00:13:14,970 --> 00:13:19,580 The firms essentially-- let me think of the best way 319 00:13:19,580 --> 00:13:20,580 describe this. 320 00:13:20,580 --> 00:13:24,625 So once again, the firms are-- from the firm's perspective, 321 00:13:24,625 --> 00:13:26,000 they do have perfect information. 322 00:13:26,000 --> 00:13:27,230 No, the wages aren't-- yes, right, 323 00:13:27,230 --> 00:13:28,070 the workers aren't the same. 324 00:13:28,070 --> 00:13:29,653 They have different marginal products. 325 00:13:29,653 --> 00:13:32,880 The firms know you're better than you or vice versa. 326 00:13:32,880 --> 00:13:34,500 But from the firm's perspective-- 327 00:13:34,500 --> 00:13:36,410 from the workers' perspective, is 328 00:13:36,410 --> 00:13:38,410 just like, think of the workers as the consumers 329 00:13:38,410 --> 00:13:40,035 in a perfect competitive output market. 330 00:13:40,035 --> 00:13:41,800 For a perfectly competitive output market, 331 00:13:41,800 --> 00:13:44,690 the consumers can easily shop across all the firms 332 00:13:44,690 --> 00:13:45,750 they might buy from. 333 00:13:45,750 --> 00:13:47,900 In a perfectly competitive input market, 334 00:13:47,900 --> 00:13:50,240 workers can easily shop among all firms 335 00:13:50,240 --> 00:13:52,580 they might work for, OK? 336 00:13:52,580 --> 00:13:53,980 That's a good question. 337 00:13:53,980 --> 00:13:55,570 Other questions? 338 00:13:55,570 --> 00:13:57,910 OK, now let's think about the long run. 339 00:13:57,910 --> 00:13:59,122 This is the short run. 340 00:13:59,122 --> 00:14:01,330 Let's think for a minute about long run labor demand. 341 00:14:03,860 --> 00:14:06,220 Think for a second about long run labor demand. 342 00:14:06,220 --> 00:14:08,095 Well, what's different? 343 00:14:08,095 --> 00:14:10,220 The only thing that's different is in the long run, 344 00:14:10,220 --> 00:14:12,365 capital can adjust as well. 345 00:14:12,365 --> 00:14:13,990 The only thing different about the long 346 00:14:13,990 --> 00:14:16,100 run-- all the intuition, everything's the same. 347 00:14:16,100 --> 00:14:19,400 It's just that capital can adjust as well. 348 00:14:19,400 --> 00:14:21,640 And what this means is that long run labor 349 00:14:21,640 --> 00:14:27,570 demand is more elastic than short run labor demand, OK? 350 00:14:27,570 --> 00:14:32,740 So we could see this in figure 15-2, OK? 351 00:14:32,740 --> 00:14:35,470 So the figure shows two different short run labor 352 00:14:35,470 --> 00:14:38,320 demand curves at two different levels of capital. 353 00:14:41,280 --> 00:14:46,070 So the short run labor demand when k bar equals 32 354 00:14:46,070 --> 00:14:47,790 is that lower one. 355 00:14:47,790 --> 00:14:49,840 The short run labor demand when k bar equals 108 356 00:14:49,840 --> 00:14:51,800 is the higher one. 357 00:14:51,800 --> 00:14:55,210 And what this says is, in the short run, 358 00:14:55,210 --> 00:14:57,730 you've got these two labor demand curves. 359 00:14:57,730 --> 00:14:59,830 In the long run, you could optimize capital. 360 00:14:59,830 --> 00:15:02,110 You can pick a point on either curve, 361 00:15:02,110 --> 00:15:04,870 depending on which level of capital you choose. 362 00:15:04,870 --> 00:15:07,390 And by definition, that allows you be more 363 00:15:07,390 --> 00:15:09,270 elastic at choosing your labor. 364 00:15:09,270 --> 00:15:10,810 You're more flexible because you can 365 00:15:10,810 --> 00:15:13,870 optimize not just over workers, but over machines as well. 366 00:15:13,870 --> 00:15:15,370 It's the same intuition we developed 367 00:15:15,370 --> 00:15:17,453 before talking about short run and long run costs, 368 00:15:17,453 --> 00:15:19,880 that the long run cost curve was a lower envelope 369 00:15:19,880 --> 00:15:21,250 than the short run cost curve. 370 00:15:21,250 --> 00:15:21,940 Same thing here. 371 00:15:21,940 --> 00:15:23,440 This applies that the long run labor 372 00:15:23,440 --> 00:15:27,568 demand is more elastic, because I basically am more flexible. 373 00:15:27,568 --> 00:15:29,110 I not only can choose a longer curve, 374 00:15:29,110 --> 00:15:30,812 I can choose which curve I use. 375 00:15:30,812 --> 00:15:32,770 And by definition, that means that the long run 376 00:15:32,770 --> 00:15:34,700 is more elastic, OK? 377 00:15:34,700 --> 00:15:37,330 Just a small sort of side point there. 378 00:15:37,330 --> 00:15:39,970 Now, the last thing I want to talk about here 379 00:15:39,970 --> 00:15:41,020 is capital demand. 380 00:15:43,493 --> 00:15:45,660 We talked about short run and long run labor demand. 381 00:15:45,660 --> 00:15:47,570 Let's talk about capital demand. 382 00:15:47,570 --> 00:15:50,030 It basically is the same thing. 383 00:15:50,030 --> 00:15:52,940 Capital demand is the exact same intuition. 384 00:15:52,940 --> 00:15:56,180 You want to get machines until the marginal product 385 00:15:56,180 --> 00:15:59,720 of capital, marginal product of the next machine, 386 00:15:59,720 --> 00:16:05,950 times the price you get for your good equals the interest rate. 387 00:16:05,950 --> 00:16:07,277 It's the same condition. 388 00:16:07,277 --> 00:16:09,360 So we want to hire workers so the marginal product 389 00:16:09,360 --> 00:16:12,150 of the labor times the price of our good equals the wage rate. 390 00:16:12,150 --> 00:16:15,422 We want to invest in more machines 391 00:16:15,422 --> 00:16:16,880 until the margin product of capital 392 00:16:16,880 --> 00:16:19,290 of the next machine times the price for our goods 393 00:16:19,290 --> 00:16:21,500 is equal to the interest rate. 394 00:16:21,500 --> 00:16:22,690 So it's exact same logic. 395 00:16:22,690 --> 00:16:23,490 Here's the marginal cost. 396 00:16:23,490 --> 00:16:24,870 The next unit of capital-- remember, 397 00:16:24,870 --> 00:16:26,120 we talked about the intuition. 398 00:16:26,120 --> 00:16:27,360 You're always renting things. 399 00:16:27,360 --> 00:16:28,980 So thinking about renting a machine, 400 00:16:28,980 --> 00:16:31,620 the next machine costs are to rent. 401 00:16:31,620 --> 00:16:32,640 Do you want to rent it? 402 00:16:32,640 --> 00:16:33,690 Well, it depends. 403 00:16:33,690 --> 00:16:37,320 What will it produce, and what can you sell that stuff for? 404 00:16:37,320 --> 00:16:39,990 So you rent the next machine if the marginal product 405 00:16:39,990 --> 00:16:41,790 of capital, if the goods it produces, 406 00:16:41,790 --> 00:16:43,680 times what you sell those goods for, you 407 00:16:43,680 --> 00:16:48,880 want to do that until that equals the interest rate, OK? 408 00:16:48,880 --> 00:16:49,970 Questions about that? 409 00:16:49,970 --> 00:16:50,568 Yeah. 410 00:16:50,568 --> 00:16:53,315 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE] machine that you buy and own? 411 00:16:53,315 --> 00:16:54,190 JONATHAN GRUBER: Yes. 412 00:16:54,190 --> 00:16:56,840 We're going to talk about that a lot starting next lecture. 413 00:16:56,840 --> 00:16:58,480 Right now, I think I'll just put this down here. 414 00:16:58,480 --> 00:16:59,980 We'll come back to it, but I'm going 415 00:16:59,980 --> 00:17:02,270 to focus on labor for this lecture, OK? 416 00:17:02,270 --> 00:17:05,964 So let's focus on labor, and let's-- so I just put that 417 00:17:05,964 --> 00:17:08,089 down, and we'll back to capital, but focus on labor 418 00:17:08,089 --> 00:17:10,589 for a minute, and make sure to understand where labor demand 419 00:17:10,589 --> 00:17:11,359 comes from. 420 00:17:11,359 --> 00:17:15,290 Now let's talk about where does labor supply come from. 421 00:17:15,290 --> 00:17:17,450 We talked about, at the firm level, 422 00:17:17,450 --> 00:17:18,970 labor supply is perfectly elastic. 423 00:17:18,970 --> 00:17:20,599 So go back to figure 15-1. 424 00:17:20,599 --> 00:17:23,810 That was a firm level curve, OK? 425 00:17:23,810 --> 00:17:25,400 That was a firm level curve. 426 00:17:25,400 --> 00:17:28,273 That's a perfectly elastic labor supply to a firm, 427 00:17:28,273 --> 00:17:29,690 but that doesn't mean labor supply 428 00:17:29,690 --> 00:17:31,580 to the market's perfectly elastic. 429 00:17:31,580 --> 00:17:34,850 So now we want to derive market labor supply. 430 00:17:34,850 --> 00:17:37,550 So I'll call this deriving market labor 431 00:17:37,550 --> 00:17:46,610 supply, deriving market labor supply, OK? 432 00:17:46,610 --> 00:17:51,020 Now, this is basically the question of, 433 00:17:51,020 --> 00:17:53,463 how do we model how hard people want to work? 434 00:17:53,463 --> 00:17:54,880 This is, once again, getting where 435 00:17:54,880 --> 00:17:58,190 the economics is exciting, OK? 436 00:17:58,190 --> 00:18:01,720 You sort of knew that economics was involved in how much Ford 437 00:18:01,720 --> 00:18:04,342 charged for a car, but you might not 438 00:18:04,342 --> 00:18:06,050 have thought so much about that economics 439 00:18:06,050 --> 00:18:10,020 was involved in deciding how hard you work, but it is. 440 00:18:10,020 --> 00:18:13,490 And we're going to use the same tools of consumer choice. 441 00:18:13,490 --> 00:18:15,920 Indeed, I used to teach this as an application of consumer 442 00:18:15,920 --> 00:18:19,280 choice, and now I teach it here, because it's the same tools 443 00:18:19,280 --> 00:18:20,360 of consumer choice. 444 00:18:20,360 --> 00:18:24,410 But now, consumers, instead of choosing good A versus good B, 445 00:18:24,410 --> 00:18:28,540 are going to choose how hard they're going to work, OK? 446 00:18:28,540 --> 00:18:33,690 So basically, like any choice, there's a tradeoff. 447 00:18:33,690 --> 00:18:34,710 There's a tradeoff. 448 00:18:34,710 --> 00:18:40,110 On the one hand, if you work harder, you get more stuff. 449 00:18:40,110 --> 00:18:41,460 So you bring home more income. 450 00:18:41,460 --> 00:18:44,280 You can buy more pizzas and cookies, OK? 451 00:18:44,280 --> 00:18:46,380 Remember, we talked about income as a fixed thing 452 00:18:46,380 --> 00:18:48,590 your parents gave you, but in reality, sorry, kids, 453 00:18:48,590 --> 00:18:51,120 you're going to have to make your own money someday. 454 00:18:51,120 --> 00:18:53,130 In reality, you're going to make a Y. It's not 455 00:18:53,130 --> 00:18:54,180 going to be given to you. 456 00:18:54,180 --> 00:18:55,860 And so if you want to buy more pizza and cookies, 457 00:18:55,860 --> 00:18:57,777 you're going to have to raise your Y. It's not 458 00:18:57,777 --> 00:18:59,430 going to be given, OK? 459 00:18:59,430 --> 00:19:01,240 So the reason you want to work harder 460 00:19:01,240 --> 00:19:03,300 is to buy more pizza and cookies. 461 00:19:03,300 --> 00:19:05,400 The reason you don't want to work harder 462 00:19:05,400 --> 00:19:08,100 is because you're not an MIT student, OK? 463 00:19:08,100 --> 00:19:12,760 That is, normal people actually don't like work, newsflash. 464 00:19:12,760 --> 00:19:14,080 OK? 465 00:19:14,080 --> 00:19:16,780 Normal people actually like leisure. 466 00:19:16,780 --> 00:19:18,980 There's a thing called leisure, it turns out, 467 00:19:18,980 --> 00:19:21,790 and normal people like it, OK? 468 00:19:21,790 --> 00:19:23,440 So the tradeoff for regular people-- 469 00:19:23,440 --> 00:19:26,530 so it's a hard thing teach at MIT-- 470 00:19:26,530 --> 00:19:29,778 is that basically, the tradeoff is if you work harder, 471 00:19:29,778 --> 00:19:31,570 you get more stuff, but you spend more time 472 00:19:31,570 --> 00:19:33,860 doing something you don't want to do. 473 00:19:33,860 --> 00:19:35,505 Now, this is weird. 474 00:19:35,505 --> 00:19:37,150 When we talked about tradeoffs before, 475 00:19:37,150 --> 00:19:39,580 we talked about the tradeoff between goods, pizza 476 00:19:39,580 --> 00:19:40,210 and cookies. 477 00:19:40,210 --> 00:19:41,710 Now we're talking about the tradeoff 478 00:19:41,710 --> 00:19:43,660 between a good and a bad. 479 00:19:43,660 --> 00:19:45,460 The good is more stuff to eat. 480 00:19:45,460 --> 00:19:47,590 The bad is working harder, and we don't really 481 00:19:47,590 --> 00:19:49,330 know how to model that. 482 00:19:49,330 --> 00:19:51,640 So the trick we're going to use here 483 00:19:51,640 --> 00:19:55,030 is we're going to flip the bad into a good. 484 00:19:55,030 --> 00:19:59,940 Instead of modeling labor, we're going to model leisure. 485 00:19:59,940 --> 00:20:03,650 So to get labor supply, we're going to model leisure supply, 486 00:20:03,650 --> 00:20:07,400 and then just flip it around to get labor supply, OK? 487 00:20:07,400 --> 00:20:13,400 So that is, we're going to say, your ultimate labor supply, 488 00:20:13,400 --> 00:20:16,760 the amount of hours you work, the amount you work, 489 00:20:16,760 --> 00:20:19,280 the amount of hours you work, call them H, 490 00:20:19,280 --> 00:20:28,760 is equal to 24 minus leisure. 491 00:20:28,760 --> 00:20:32,240 Let's call it leisure, because leisure's called little l. 492 00:20:32,240 --> 00:20:33,470 Leisure's little l. 493 00:20:33,470 --> 00:20:36,260 The amount of hours you work is 24 minus the hours of leisure 494 00:20:36,260 --> 00:20:37,490 you take. 495 00:20:37,490 --> 00:20:41,450 What that means is I don't have to model the bad. 496 00:20:41,450 --> 00:20:45,200 I can model the good and just use this simple reflection 497 00:20:45,200 --> 00:20:47,708 equation to get the bad, OK? 498 00:20:47,708 --> 00:20:49,125 So this is the trick in economics. 499 00:20:49,125 --> 00:20:50,390 It's a good modeling trick. 500 00:20:50,390 --> 00:20:51,545 We don't model bad so we don't have 501 00:20:51,545 --> 00:20:53,100 to do the tradeoff between the bad and the good. 502 00:20:53,100 --> 00:20:55,225 We don't have to do the tradeoff between two goods. 503 00:20:55,225 --> 00:20:56,480 So turn the bad into a good. 504 00:20:56,480 --> 00:20:59,200 Don't model work, model leisure. 505 00:20:59,200 --> 00:21:01,700 Don't model your hours you work, model how many 506 00:21:01,700 --> 00:21:03,710 hours of leisure, OK? 507 00:21:03,710 --> 00:21:05,160 This is a general modeling trick. 508 00:21:05,160 --> 00:21:07,860 So what we want to ask is, now, not how 509 00:21:07,860 --> 00:21:09,780 do you derive the supply of labor, 510 00:21:09,780 --> 00:21:13,190 how do you derive the demand for leisure? 511 00:21:13,190 --> 00:21:16,230 How do we derive how much leisure people want? 512 00:21:16,230 --> 00:21:18,927 Well, once I say it that way, you know what to do, 513 00:21:18,927 --> 00:21:20,010 which is what I just said. 514 00:21:20,010 --> 00:21:23,490 There are two goods, consumption and leisure. 515 00:21:23,490 --> 00:21:25,440 I wonder how much of one good you choose-- 516 00:21:25,440 --> 00:21:26,490 of each good you choose. 517 00:21:26,490 --> 00:21:28,830 Well, that's a consumer choice problem. 518 00:21:28,830 --> 00:21:31,110 You know how to do that, OK? 519 00:21:31,110 --> 00:21:36,430 So basically, take figure 15-3, OK? 520 00:21:36,430 --> 00:21:40,570 In figure 15-3, now, instead of doing pizza versus cookies, 521 00:21:40,570 --> 00:21:42,360 now our decision is all consumption. 522 00:21:42,360 --> 00:21:44,360 So we're thinking about consumption as a bundle, 523 00:21:44,360 --> 00:21:47,240 OK, versus leisure. 524 00:21:47,240 --> 00:21:51,490 So on the y-axis is the goods you choose. 525 00:21:51,490 --> 00:21:55,560 On the x-axis is how much leisure you take, OK? 526 00:21:55,560 --> 00:21:59,070 It says N but actually it should be little l, OK? 527 00:21:59,070 --> 00:22:00,900 Should be little l. 528 00:22:00,900 --> 00:22:03,230 So let's call that little l, OK? 529 00:22:03,230 --> 00:22:08,560 So basically, as you go more positive on the x-axis, 530 00:22:08,560 --> 00:22:09,610 that's more leisure. 531 00:22:09,610 --> 00:22:11,380 But because this equation, that implies 532 00:22:11,380 --> 00:22:14,200 as you go to the left on the axis, that's more work, OK? 533 00:22:14,200 --> 00:22:15,820 Yeah. 534 00:22:15,820 --> 00:22:17,360 H is hours of work. 535 00:22:17,360 --> 00:22:18,260 H is hours of work. 536 00:22:18,260 --> 00:22:20,353 So as you go to the left, you work more. 537 00:22:20,353 --> 00:22:22,270 As you go to the right, you take more leisure. 538 00:22:22,270 --> 00:22:24,500 But we're modeling the good, which is leisure. 539 00:22:24,500 --> 00:22:28,600 And then we just go to our standard-- 540 00:22:28,600 --> 00:22:31,990 we go to our standard consumer choice equation. 541 00:22:31,990 --> 00:22:34,180 We have a budget constraint and preferences. 542 00:22:34,180 --> 00:22:38,730 The indifference curve comes from your utility function. 543 00:22:38,730 --> 00:22:44,430 It comes from your indifference between how much you consume 544 00:22:44,430 --> 00:22:45,897 and how much leisure you take. 545 00:22:45,897 --> 00:22:48,480 And the indifference curve comes from like any consumer choice 546 00:22:48,480 --> 00:22:49,017 decision. 547 00:22:49,017 --> 00:22:51,100 But instead of choosing between pizza and cookies, 548 00:22:51,100 --> 00:22:52,920 now it's how much stuff you want versus how much leisure you 549 00:22:52,920 --> 00:22:54,070 want to take. 550 00:22:54,070 --> 00:22:56,220 So it's the same sort of indifference curve. 551 00:22:56,220 --> 00:23:01,840 The budget constraint comes from what the market tells 552 00:23:01,840 --> 00:23:04,420 you is the cost of leisure. 553 00:23:04,420 --> 00:23:07,790 What is the price of leisure? 554 00:23:07,790 --> 00:23:10,928 What is the price of leisure? 555 00:23:10,928 --> 00:23:11,470 Someone else? 556 00:23:11,470 --> 00:23:12,760 Someone else got it? 557 00:23:12,760 --> 00:23:13,330 Yeah, 558 00:23:13,330 --> 00:23:14,010 AUDIENCE: Your wage. 559 00:23:14,010 --> 00:23:14,380 JONATHAN GRUBER: Your wage. 560 00:23:14,380 --> 00:23:15,755 Why is that the price of leisure? 561 00:23:15,755 --> 00:23:17,338 AUDIENCE: Because every hour you don't 562 00:23:17,338 --> 00:23:19,340 work is another hour of wage you don't get. 563 00:23:19,340 --> 00:23:21,340 JONATHAN GRUBER: Which we call what? 564 00:23:21,340 --> 00:23:21,880 AUDIENCE: Opportunity cost. 565 00:23:21,880 --> 00:23:22,250 JONATHAN GRUBER: Opportunity cost. 566 00:23:22,250 --> 00:23:24,190 Remember, prices and opportunity cost 567 00:23:24,190 --> 00:23:25,780 are the same thing in economics. 568 00:23:25,780 --> 00:23:28,405 Here's once again where it gets interesting to apply what we've 569 00:23:28,405 --> 00:23:30,130 learned, which is that basically, this 570 00:23:30,130 --> 00:23:32,680 is why, once again, they call economics the dismal science. 571 00:23:32,680 --> 00:23:34,470 Instead of having fun sitting around, 572 00:23:34,470 --> 00:23:36,790 we're telling you, you know, by the way, 573 00:23:36,790 --> 00:23:38,440 you could be working and making a wage. 574 00:23:38,440 --> 00:23:41,940 So you're actually spending money by taking leisure. 575 00:23:41,940 --> 00:23:43,710 By taking leisure, you are spending money. 576 00:23:43,710 --> 00:23:44,910 What are you spending? 577 00:23:44,910 --> 00:23:47,950 You're spending the money you could be earning. 578 00:23:47,950 --> 00:23:51,270 So the opportunity-- so leisure has a price, 579 00:23:51,270 --> 00:23:54,150 and the price of leisure is the wage. 580 00:23:54,150 --> 00:23:56,340 It's what you could be earning if you were working. 581 00:23:56,340 --> 00:24:00,210 So the budget constraint has the slope of minus w. 582 00:24:00,210 --> 00:24:02,250 So if you look at the budget constraint, 583 00:24:02,250 --> 00:24:05,250 you could take 24 hours of leisure 584 00:24:05,250 --> 00:24:07,920 and have zero consumption, OK? 585 00:24:07,920 --> 00:24:10,530 That's the x-axis intercept. 586 00:24:10,530 --> 00:24:17,460 Or you take no leisure and have 24w worth of consumption, OK? 587 00:24:17,460 --> 00:24:21,528 So basically, that is the tradeoff you face. 588 00:24:21,528 --> 00:24:23,320 One other modeling trick-- couple of them-- 589 00:24:23,320 --> 00:24:24,820 so a couple of modeling tricks here. 590 00:24:24,820 --> 00:24:28,840 Modeling trick one is modeling the good, not the bad, OK? 591 00:24:28,840 --> 00:24:33,105 Modeling trick two is, I wrote on the x-axis goods, 592 00:24:33,105 --> 00:24:34,480 but we don't think in quantities, 593 00:24:34,480 --> 00:24:36,080 we think in dollars. 594 00:24:36,080 --> 00:24:37,580 So to make life easier, I just said, 595 00:24:37,580 --> 00:24:41,190 let's assume the price of the average good is $1. 596 00:24:41,190 --> 00:24:42,480 That way you can-- 597 00:24:42,480 --> 00:24:45,810 that's called-- that's just a normalization, OK, 598 00:24:45,810 --> 00:24:48,060 which allows you to think in terms of dollars of goods 599 00:24:48,060 --> 00:24:49,310 rather than quantity of goods. 600 00:24:49,310 --> 00:24:51,060 That's another modeling trick we'll do. 601 00:24:51,060 --> 00:24:53,788 We call it making a numerator good, OK? 602 00:24:53,788 --> 00:24:55,330 You don't have to remember that term, 603 00:24:55,330 --> 00:24:56,705 but the point is a trick we'll do 604 00:24:56,705 --> 00:24:58,660 is we want to model dollars, not quantities. 605 00:24:58,660 --> 00:25:00,580 We just make the quantities cost $1, 606 00:25:00,580 --> 00:25:03,030 and then we can model quantities basically as dollars. 607 00:25:03,030 --> 00:25:04,363 So that's the trick we're doing. 608 00:25:04,363 --> 00:25:07,150 So the y-axis is dollars, but it's also quantities, 609 00:25:07,150 --> 00:25:10,052 because we made the price of everything be $1, OK? 610 00:25:10,052 --> 00:25:12,010 It's just another trick that makes life easier. 611 00:25:12,010 --> 00:25:15,140 OK, so two modeling tricks here, the numerator trick, 612 00:25:15,140 --> 00:25:18,760 which is making the price $1 so quantities become dollars, 613 00:25:18,760 --> 00:25:21,460 and the bad is good trick, which is model the good, 614 00:25:21,460 --> 00:25:23,410 and then reverse that to get the bad. 615 00:25:23,410 --> 00:25:25,360 Having done that, we know what to do. 616 00:25:25,360 --> 00:25:27,550 We get an optimum, which is the tendency 617 00:25:27,550 --> 00:25:30,730 between the indifference curve and the budget constraint, 618 00:25:30,730 --> 00:25:32,550 and we're done. 619 00:25:32,550 --> 00:25:33,630 And so what do you do? 620 00:25:33,630 --> 00:25:36,550 You choose-- we're going to call this L. We'll call it little l. 621 00:25:36,550 --> 00:25:40,650 You choose little l star hours of leisure, 622 00:25:40,650 --> 00:25:45,660 which means you choose 24 minus little l star hours of work, 623 00:25:45,660 --> 00:25:46,190 OK? 624 00:25:46,190 --> 00:25:47,210 So basically, you sat down. 625 00:25:47,210 --> 00:25:48,627 You made the decision, how much do 626 00:25:48,627 --> 00:25:51,520 I want to eat versus how much do I want to watch TV. 627 00:25:51,520 --> 00:25:54,680 You make that tradeoff, and that determines how hard you work, 628 00:25:54,680 --> 00:25:55,700 OK? 629 00:25:55,700 --> 00:25:56,680 Now-- yeah. 630 00:26:00,020 --> 00:26:03,230 AUDIENCE: Aren't there things that are kind of necessary? 631 00:26:03,230 --> 00:26:06,220 Like for example, if you wanted to-- like 632 00:26:06,220 --> 00:26:11,213 if your preference was completely to work, 633 00:26:11,213 --> 00:26:13,130 then wouldn't we be like an inefficient worker 634 00:26:13,130 --> 00:26:14,110 if we didn't sleep? 635 00:26:14,110 --> 00:26:14,862 Doesn't-- 636 00:26:14,862 --> 00:26:16,570 JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, and in some sense, 637 00:26:16,570 --> 00:26:19,610 that would be in your utility function, 638 00:26:19,610 --> 00:26:21,240 or it would be in your utility function 639 00:26:21,240 --> 00:26:22,490 and/or your budget constraint. 640 00:26:22,490 --> 00:26:23,900 That would be true, absolutely. 641 00:26:23,900 --> 00:26:25,492 But that would be a feature. 642 00:26:25,492 --> 00:26:27,450 That wouldn't change this maximization problem. 643 00:26:27,450 --> 00:26:28,867 It'd just change general structure 644 00:26:28,867 --> 00:26:32,830 of the equations that go into the maximization problem, OK? 645 00:26:32,830 --> 00:26:37,197 So basically, now, what's really interesting about this is now 646 00:26:37,197 --> 00:26:39,280 we finally understand why we learned all that shit 647 00:26:39,280 --> 00:26:40,963 about income and substitution effects. 648 00:26:40,963 --> 00:26:42,880 Remember, let's think of substitution effects. 649 00:26:42,880 --> 00:26:44,880 And you're probably saying like, "Why do I care? 650 00:26:44,880 --> 00:26:45,628 Price goes up. 651 00:26:45,628 --> 00:26:46,420 Quantity goes down. 652 00:26:46,420 --> 00:26:47,350 Why do I care?" 653 00:26:47,350 --> 00:26:53,350 Here's why you care, because now it gets really interesting, OK? 654 00:26:53,350 --> 00:26:55,690 Because when we're doing substitution effects 655 00:26:55,690 --> 00:26:57,670 for a good, they work together. 656 00:26:57,670 --> 00:27:00,623 As long as the good was normal, they work together. 657 00:27:00,623 --> 00:27:03,040 When the price went up, you substituted away from the good 658 00:27:03,040 --> 00:27:04,350 and you are poor. 659 00:27:04,350 --> 00:27:06,370 So it gets substituted down for two reasons. 660 00:27:06,370 --> 00:27:13,970 Now, a normal leisure effect is an inferior labor effect. 661 00:27:13,970 --> 00:27:19,040 What I mean by that is that when your wage goes up, 662 00:27:19,040 --> 00:27:22,220 you work more through the substitution effect, but now 663 00:27:22,220 --> 00:27:23,780 you're richer. 664 00:27:23,780 --> 00:27:26,820 And when you're richer, you buy more of everything, 665 00:27:26,820 --> 00:27:28,530 including leisure. 666 00:27:28,530 --> 00:27:31,820 So if you take more leisure, you do less labor. 667 00:27:31,820 --> 00:27:34,870 So the income effect naturally goes against the substitution 668 00:27:34,870 --> 00:27:35,370 effect. 669 00:27:35,370 --> 00:27:36,240 I'll go through this a couple of times. 670 00:27:36,240 --> 00:27:37,060 Don't worry. 671 00:27:37,060 --> 00:27:39,260 The income effect naturally goes against the substitution effect 672 00:27:39,260 --> 00:27:39,860 here. 673 00:27:39,860 --> 00:27:42,200 For consumption goods, the income effect 674 00:27:42,200 --> 00:27:44,910 naturally work together, OK? 675 00:27:44,910 --> 00:27:47,180 We almost never saw sort of a Giffen good type 676 00:27:47,180 --> 00:27:49,610 phenomenon, where the effect could sort of switch 677 00:27:49,610 --> 00:27:50,960 the overall effect. 678 00:27:50,960 --> 00:27:52,520 For labor, that's much more likely, 679 00:27:52,520 --> 00:27:58,370 and it's much more likely not because of any inferior good. 680 00:27:58,370 --> 00:28:00,470 It's because leisure is a normal good, 681 00:28:00,470 --> 00:28:02,940 and labor is the opposite of leisure. 682 00:28:02,940 --> 00:28:04,590 So once again, let me say it again. 683 00:28:04,590 --> 00:28:06,820 The wage goes up. 684 00:28:06,820 --> 00:28:11,590 The substitution effect-- think of leisure as a good. 685 00:28:11,590 --> 00:28:15,350 When the wage goes up, that's the price of leisure going up. 686 00:28:15,350 --> 00:28:17,660 When the price of a good goes up, 687 00:28:17,660 --> 00:28:21,220 the substitution effects says you want less of it, OK? 688 00:28:21,220 --> 00:28:26,980 So when the wage goes up, the substitution effect 689 00:28:26,980 --> 00:28:31,530 says that leisure goes down, right? 690 00:28:31,530 --> 00:28:33,300 Because you want to substitute-- wait, 691 00:28:33,300 --> 00:28:35,160 leisure just got more expensive. 692 00:28:35,160 --> 00:28:37,260 You now feel worse sitting around watching TV, 693 00:28:37,260 --> 00:28:39,570 because you could be out there making more money. 694 00:28:39,570 --> 00:28:41,264 Yeah. 695 00:28:41,264 --> 00:28:43,256 AUDIENCE: Wouldn't income-- [COUGHS] 696 00:28:43,256 --> 00:28:43,760 JONATHAN GRUBER: I haven't got to income effect. 697 00:28:43,760 --> 00:28:45,395 Let me finish, then you can ask it. 698 00:28:45,395 --> 00:28:46,640 AUDIENCE: Wouldn't income effect be-- 699 00:28:46,640 --> 00:28:47,640 JONATHAN GRUBER: I haven't gotten to the income effects. 700 00:28:47,640 --> 00:28:50,460 Let me ask finish, then you can ask it, OK? 701 00:28:50,460 --> 00:28:54,990 So the substitution effect says that leisure goes down, OK? 702 00:28:54,990 --> 00:29:01,250 The income effect says that you are richer, right? 703 00:29:01,250 --> 00:29:02,710 Your wage went up. 704 00:29:02,710 --> 00:29:03,950 You're richer. 705 00:29:03,950 --> 00:29:07,630 When you're richer, you want more of all normal goods. 706 00:29:07,630 --> 00:29:12,160 Leisure for non-MIT students is a normal good. 707 00:29:12,160 --> 00:29:13,380 So you want more of it. 708 00:29:16,790 --> 00:29:20,920 So here, with consumption goods, when they were normal, 709 00:29:20,920 --> 00:29:23,770 the income and substitution effects work together. 710 00:29:23,770 --> 00:29:27,163 With labor and leisure, they work opposite. 711 00:29:27,163 --> 00:29:28,830 So what this is, the substitution effect 712 00:29:28,830 --> 00:29:32,320 says take more leisure, which means work-- 713 00:29:32,320 --> 00:29:35,170 take less leisure means work harder, work more hours. 714 00:29:35,170 --> 00:29:37,120 But the income effect says take more leisure, 715 00:29:37,120 --> 00:29:40,420 which means work less hours. 716 00:29:40,420 --> 00:29:44,083 So you don't know what the net effect is. 717 00:29:44,083 --> 00:29:46,250 So that's why we do income and substitution effects, 718 00:29:46,250 --> 00:29:48,070 because in a case like this, they get much more interesting. 719 00:29:48,070 --> 00:29:49,028 Yes, now your question. 720 00:29:49,028 --> 00:29:52,310 AUDIENCE: Is this income effect in terms of income over time? 721 00:29:52,310 --> 00:29:53,870 JONATHAN GRUBER: No, this is your income, your actual cash 722 00:29:53,870 --> 00:29:54,380 income. 723 00:29:54,380 --> 00:29:57,140 You are now richer, and when you're richer, 724 00:29:57,140 --> 00:29:58,520 you spend more on everything. 725 00:29:58,520 --> 00:29:59,280 So think of it this way. 726 00:29:59,280 --> 00:30:00,910 Once again, imagine you're not an MIT student. 727 00:30:00,910 --> 00:30:01,960 You're a normal guy. 728 00:30:01,960 --> 00:30:05,260 OK, if we won the lottery, if you guys won the lottery, 729 00:30:05,260 --> 00:30:07,520 you would use that to do a startup. 730 00:30:07,520 --> 00:30:09,240 If a normal person won the lottery, 731 00:30:09,240 --> 00:30:12,440 they'd use it to not work, OK? 732 00:30:12,440 --> 00:30:13,928 That's the income effect. 733 00:30:13,928 --> 00:30:15,470 OK, when normal people win lotteries, 734 00:30:15,470 --> 00:30:16,970 they don't go work harder. 735 00:30:16,970 --> 00:30:19,040 They don't work, OK? 736 00:30:19,040 --> 00:30:20,270 So that's the point. 737 00:30:20,270 --> 00:30:23,130 You are now richer because your wage went up. 738 00:30:23,130 --> 00:30:25,550 So you work less, and that offsets it. 739 00:30:25,550 --> 00:30:27,180 So let's show this in a graph. 740 00:30:27,180 --> 00:30:29,555 Let's go back to our income and substitution effect graph 741 00:30:29,555 --> 00:30:33,108 that we did before, figure 15-4, OK? 742 00:30:33,108 --> 00:30:33,900 Now we're back to-- 743 00:30:33,900 --> 00:30:36,870 once again, this is just applied consumer theory, OK? 744 00:30:36,870 --> 00:30:39,270 Let's go back to the income and substitution effects. 745 00:30:39,270 --> 00:30:42,840 We start with budget constraint one at wage one, 746 00:30:42,840 --> 00:30:47,630 and we have our initial tangency at A, OK, with leisure of N1 747 00:30:47,630 --> 00:30:50,450 or little l1. 748 00:30:50,450 --> 00:30:53,450 Now our wage goes up. 749 00:30:53,450 --> 00:30:54,260 Our wage goes up. 750 00:30:54,260 --> 00:30:56,880 Therefore, the budget constraint pivots up. 751 00:30:56,880 --> 00:30:58,250 Think of what that means. 752 00:30:58,250 --> 00:31:00,500 You can still only have 24 hours of leisure. 753 00:31:00,500 --> 00:31:02,090 That's a fixed point. 754 00:31:02,090 --> 00:31:06,290 But as you take less leisure, you make more money. 755 00:31:06,290 --> 00:31:08,510 So the budget trade now pivots up. 756 00:31:08,510 --> 00:31:10,340 Well, that has two effects. 757 00:31:10,340 --> 00:31:12,980 The first is the substitution effect. 758 00:31:12,980 --> 00:31:14,090 Remember how we get that. 759 00:31:14,090 --> 00:31:16,370 We draw an imaginary budget constraint 760 00:31:16,370 --> 00:31:18,812 at the new price ratio. 761 00:31:18,812 --> 00:31:20,270 The price ratio is just W because I 762 00:31:20,270 --> 00:31:22,570 assume the price of goods is 1. 763 00:31:22,570 --> 00:31:25,390 The new price ratio, tangent to the old indifference 764 00:31:25,390 --> 00:31:29,970 curve, that is point B. So the substitution effect says, 765 00:31:29,970 --> 00:31:35,000 take less leisure, OK? 766 00:31:35,000 --> 00:31:38,660 The price of leisure has gone up, so holding utility costs, 767 00:31:38,660 --> 00:31:40,760 you want to take less leisure. 768 00:31:40,760 --> 00:31:42,560 The income effect, however, says, 769 00:31:42,560 --> 00:31:46,326 you are now richer so take more leisure. 770 00:31:46,326 --> 00:31:48,450 So the income effect goes the opposite way 771 00:31:48,450 --> 00:31:50,440 of the substitution effect naturally. 772 00:31:50,440 --> 00:31:52,440 You don't need a weird thing for that to happen, 773 00:31:52,440 --> 00:31:53,790 like with pizza and cookies. 774 00:31:53,790 --> 00:31:55,680 It comes naturally. 775 00:31:55,680 --> 00:31:59,370 So for normal goods, the income effect goes the opposite way. 776 00:31:59,370 --> 00:32:03,150 Now, in this case, we end up with leisure still going down. 777 00:32:03,150 --> 00:32:06,060 We end up with, the wage goes up, leisure goes down, 778 00:32:06,060 --> 00:32:07,612 and therefore labor supply goes up. 779 00:32:07,612 --> 00:32:09,570 So we end up with our standard intuition, which 780 00:32:09,570 --> 00:32:11,220 is, I tell you, if I'm going to pay you more, 781 00:32:11,220 --> 00:32:12,928 you're going to work harder or less hard? 782 00:32:12,928 --> 00:32:16,280 The standard intuition is I work more hard, OK? 783 00:32:16,280 --> 00:32:19,910 But as figure 15-5 shows, it would not 784 00:32:19,910 --> 00:32:24,520 be super odd to get a Giffen good effect here, 785 00:32:24,520 --> 00:32:27,430 which is, the wage goes up. 786 00:32:27,430 --> 00:32:29,740 The substitution effect shifts you to the left, 787 00:32:29,740 --> 00:32:32,620 but the income effect shifts you even more to the right, 788 00:32:32,620 --> 00:32:37,380 and you actually end up with more leisure. 789 00:32:37,380 --> 00:32:40,910 So once again, my intuition, if I say to you the price of pizza 790 00:32:40,910 --> 00:32:43,310 went up, what happens to your demand for pizza? 791 00:32:43,310 --> 00:32:45,250 You think of a standard-- you say, "Well, I'm 792 00:32:45,250 --> 00:32:46,580 going to demand less pizza." 793 00:32:46,580 --> 00:32:48,260 If I say to you the wage went up, 794 00:32:48,260 --> 00:32:50,570 what happened to how hard you work? 795 00:32:50,570 --> 00:32:52,980 It's not clear. 796 00:32:52,980 --> 00:32:55,080 Think of a simple example. 797 00:32:55,080 --> 00:32:56,843 Think of yourself actually back before you 798 00:32:56,843 --> 00:32:58,260 were an MIT student, when you were 799 00:32:58,260 --> 00:33:00,330 a kid saving for something. 800 00:33:00,330 --> 00:33:04,910 You were saving to buy a bike, and the bike was $150. 801 00:33:04,910 --> 00:33:09,500 OK, bike was $200, and you're earning $10 an hour, OK? 802 00:33:09,500 --> 00:33:12,550 So you had to work 20 hours to get the bike. 803 00:33:12,550 --> 00:33:16,270 Now I gave you a raise to 15 hours-- 804 00:33:16,270 --> 00:33:19,360 to $15 an hour or $20 an hour. 805 00:33:19,360 --> 00:33:21,670 Would you work harder or less hard? 806 00:33:21,670 --> 00:33:24,207 Well, if all you want is the bike, you'd work less hard. 807 00:33:24,207 --> 00:33:25,540 You don't have to work 20 hours. 808 00:33:25,540 --> 00:33:27,150 You only have to work 10 hours. 809 00:33:27,150 --> 00:33:29,830 So in fact, a higher wage caused you to work less hard. 810 00:33:29,830 --> 00:33:31,690 That's not that bizarre a case, right? 811 00:33:31,690 --> 00:33:33,190 That makes sense. 812 00:33:33,190 --> 00:33:36,010 The point is, it's actually quite sensible 813 00:33:36,010 --> 00:33:38,620 that you couldn't end up with the labor supply being a Giffen 814 00:33:38,620 --> 00:33:42,160 good, with a higher wage causing you to work less. 815 00:33:42,160 --> 00:33:43,590 It's not a crazy outcome. 816 00:33:43,590 --> 00:33:45,790 Giffen goods and consumer goods are crazy. 817 00:33:45,790 --> 00:33:48,820 It's not at all crazy to think that in cases 818 00:33:48,820 --> 00:33:51,023 like having a target, a purchase target, 819 00:33:51,023 --> 00:33:52,940 a higher wage would cause people to work less. 820 00:33:52,940 --> 00:33:53,516 Yeah. 821 00:33:53,516 --> 00:33:58,090 AUDIENCE: So does the law of nonsatiation not apply? 822 00:33:58,090 --> 00:34:01,060 JONATHAN GRUBER: Absolute applies. 823 00:34:01,060 --> 00:34:02,075 Absolutely applies. 824 00:34:02,075 --> 00:34:02,950 There's no violation. 825 00:34:02,950 --> 00:34:04,630 We haven't violated any of the laws. 826 00:34:04,630 --> 00:34:06,700 All we've done is just said income effects-- 827 00:34:06,700 --> 00:34:08,915 it didn't apply with Giffen goods too. 828 00:34:08,915 --> 00:34:11,290 It's all just saying income effects dominate substitution 829 00:34:11,290 --> 00:34:12,880 effects, which we thought was sort 830 00:34:12,880 --> 00:34:15,850 of going to be pretty bizarre in the consumption good context, 831 00:34:15,850 --> 00:34:18,562 but it's not at all bizarre in the labor supply context. 832 00:34:18,562 --> 00:34:20,130 So this is pretty wild. 833 00:34:20,130 --> 00:34:22,889 What this says is that basically, you've 834 00:34:22,889 --> 00:34:25,830 got a situation where even in the normal world, 835 00:34:25,830 --> 00:34:27,330 you can get that paying workers more 836 00:34:27,330 --> 00:34:32,310 makes them work less, which is kind of bizarre, OK? 837 00:34:32,310 --> 00:34:34,727 Questions about that, about that intuition, or the math, 838 00:34:34,727 --> 00:34:35,310 or the graphs? 839 00:34:35,310 --> 00:34:37,040 Well, the math we haven't done, but the graphs? 840 00:34:37,040 --> 00:34:38,260 We'll do the math on Friday. 841 00:34:38,260 --> 00:34:40,659 The graphs or anything? 842 00:34:40,659 --> 00:34:41,810 OK. 843 00:34:41,810 --> 00:34:45,230 Let's then say, well, does that happen in reality? 844 00:34:45,230 --> 00:34:46,440 What does the evidence say? 845 00:34:49,500 --> 00:34:51,010 Let's go to the evidence. 846 00:34:51,010 --> 00:34:53,989 What does the evidence say? 847 00:34:53,989 --> 00:34:56,480 And there may be sort of no question more 848 00:34:56,480 --> 00:35:00,440 worked on in economics than the elasticity of labor supply 849 00:35:00,440 --> 00:35:02,880 or the shape of the labor supply curve. 850 00:35:02,880 --> 00:35:07,530 There is thousands of articles written on this question, OK? 851 00:35:07,530 --> 00:35:10,810 And what I want to do here to make the intuition easy, 852 00:35:10,810 --> 00:35:13,560 I want to go back to the literature circa 853 00:35:13,560 --> 00:35:15,143 probably 40 years ago, when it was 854 00:35:15,143 --> 00:35:17,060 sort of the initial burst of interest in this, 855 00:35:17,060 --> 00:35:18,800 in like the 1970s. 856 00:35:18,800 --> 00:35:20,900 In 1970s, there was a burst of interest in this. 857 00:35:20,900 --> 00:35:24,170 And what the literature did was it looked separately 858 00:35:24,170 --> 00:35:28,100 at men and married women, because most of women 859 00:35:28,100 --> 00:35:30,840 were married, and back then we didn't care about single women, 860 00:35:30,840 --> 00:35:33,520 OK? 861 00:35:33,520 --> 00:35:36,800 OK, it was a dark time, OK? 862 00:35:36,800 --> 00:35:39,200 So the literature looked at men and women, 863 00:35:39,200 --> 00:35:41,330 and married women, and asked what 864 00:35:41,330 --> 00:35:44,420 was their elasticity of labor supply. 865 00:35:44,420 --> 00:35:47,350 Well, let's think for a second about what we'd expect, 866 00:35:47,350 --> 00:35:51,740 and to do that, let's think about the substitution effect 867 00:35:51,740 --> 00:35:53,570 and the income effect. 868 00:35:53,570 --> 00:35:58,962 Let's start with men, the male substitution effect. 869 00:35:58,962 --> 00:36:00,170 Let's go substitution effect. 870 00:36:00,170 --> 00:36:04,080 Men versus married women, who has a bigger substitution 871 00:36:04,080 --> 00:36:05,400 effect and why? 872 00:36:05,400 --> 00:36:10,500 That is, when the wage goes up, who has a bigger substitution 873 00:36:10,500 --> 00:36:12,405 response to that and why? 874 00:36:12,405 --> 00:36:13,280 Men or married women? 875 00:36:16,490 --> 00:36:18,910 Think about the world-- 876 00:36:18,910 --> 00:36:21,030 think about the Mad Men world or the world, 877 00:36:21,030 --> 00:36:22,285 you know, circa 40 years ago. 878 00:36:22,285 --> 00:36:23,660 You guys seen enough TV and stuff 879 00:36:23,660 --> 00:36:26,387 to know how life was a little bit, OK? 880 00:36:26,387 --> 00:36:27,470 So who's going to respond? 881 00:36:27,470 --> 00:36:28,562 Who's the bigger-- yeah. 882 00:36:28,562 --> 00:36:30,530 AUDIENCE: Are you assuming men were primary providers? 883 00:36:30,530 --> 00:36:32,550 JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, they certainly were in the 1970s. 884 00:36:32,550 --> 00:36:33,258 AUDIENCE: Oh, OK. 885 00:36:33,258 --> 00:36:34,340 In that case, the men. 886 00:36:34,340 --> 00:36:35,750 JONATHAN GRUBER: Men have a bigger substitution effect? 887 00:36:35,750 --> 00:36:38,210 AUDIENCE: Yeah, they'll work more, probably. 888 00:36:38,210 --> 00:36:41,520 JONATHAN GRUBER: OK, that's one option, yeah. 889 00:36:41,520 --> 00:36:44,110 AUDIENCE: It'll be married women, because they're only 890 00:36:44,110 --> 00:36:45,322 working if they have to. 891 00:36:45,322 --> 00:36:46,280 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 892 00:36:46,280 --> 00:36:48,613 So it's actually married women, because men were already 893 00:36:48,613 --> 00:36:50,300 working 40 hours. 894 00:36:50,300 --> 00:36:52,220 They can't-- there's no-- 895 00:36:52,220 --> 00:36:55,050 So think about a married man in 1975. 896 00:36:55,050 --> 00:36:56,477 OK, men didn't raise their kids. 897 00:36:56,477 --> 00:36:58,310 Men quite frankly didn't give much of a shit 898 00:36:58,310 --> 00:37:00,650 about their kids, OK? 899 00:37:00,650 --> 00:37:01,670 Men just worked. 900 00:37:01,670 --> 00:37:04,807 That's what men did in 1975, OK? 901 00:37:04,807 --> 00:37:06,640 They worked, and they worked their 40 hours, 902 00:37:06,640 --> 00:37:07,890 and then went home. 903 00:37:07,890 --> 00:37:10,050 OK, maybe they worked less or more than 40 hours, 904 00:37:10,050 --> 00:37:11,630 but certainly, the notion of saying, 905 00:37:11,630 --> 00:37:12,630 "Well, the wage went up. 906 00:37:12,630 --> 00:37:14,970 Maybe I'll take more leisure," never really crossed 907 00:37:14,970 --> 00:37:16,712 a man's mind in 1975. 908 00:37:16,712 --> 00:37:18,170 Because what were they going to do? 909 00:37:18,170 --> 00:37:19,628 They have no one to play golf with. 910 00:37:19,628 --> 00:37:22,050 They didn't want to spend time with their kids. 911 00:37:22,050 --> 00:37:23,610 What were they going to do? 912 00:37:23,610 --> 00:37:28,110 Whereas women had a real substitution possibility, OK? 913 00:37:28,110 --> 00:37:31,650 This was an era women were entering the labor force. 914 00:37:31,650 --> 00:37:33,300 There were real opportunities for work, 915 00:37:33,300 --> 00:37:35,750 but it was also fine to hang out at home. 916 00:37:35,750 --> 00:37:37,260 You had-- a lot of your friends were hanging out at home. 917 00:37:37,260 --> 00:37:38,190 You could take care of kids. 918 00:37:38,190 --> 00:37:39,750 There were a lot of things to do. 919 00:37:39,750 --> 00:37:46,270 So women had a much larger substitution effect than men, 920 00:37:46,270 --> 00:37:46,840 OK? 921 00:37:46,840 --> 00:37:50,260 Because men-- remember, what's the substitution effect? 922 00:37:50,260 --> 00:37:52,780 It's about the next best alternative. 923 00:37:52,780 --> 00:37:54,840 For men, there was no next best alternative. 924 00:37:54,840 --> 00:37:55,915 It was just work. 925 00:37:55,915 --> 00:37:57,790 Basically, between 9:00 to 5:00 on a weekday, 926 00:37:57,790 --> 00:38:00,280 there was nothing else to do, OK? 927 00:38:00,280 --> 00:38:01,980 For women, there was other things to do, 928 00:38:01,980 --> 00:38:04,480 which is, you can hang out with friends who weren't working, 929 00:38:04,480 --> 00:38:06,170 or you could take care of the kids. 930 00:38:06,170 --> 00:38:06,670 Yeah. 931 00:38:06,670 --> 00:38:08,628 AUDIENCE: But what about like working overtime? 932 00:38:08,628 --> 00:38:10,790 JONATHAN GRUBER: OK, well, let's-- but once again, 933 00:38:10,790 --> 00:38:13,270 if I'm a man, you might think that I could then-- 934 00:38:13,270 --> 00:38:15,400 but then once again, if I work-- 935 00:38:15,400 --> 00:38:18,227 the substitution effect could work that way for overtime. 936 00:38:18,227 --> 00:38:19,810 But let's talk about just the decision 937 00:38:19,810 --> 00:38:22,360 to work at all, in some sense, or the decision 938 00:38:22,360 --> 00:38:23,860 to work sort of your first 40 hours. 939 00:38:23,860 --> 00:38:26,360 Overtime is hard, because then you get paid more, et cetera. 940 00:38:26,360 --> 00:38:28,340 OK, now let's go to the other side. 941 00:38:28,340 --> 00:38:29,810 Let's go to the income effect. 942 00:38:29,810 --> 00:38:31,150 So let's not say this is zero. 943 00:38:31,150 --> 00:38:35,205 Let's say it's small, because this is big and this is small. 944 00:38:35,205 --> 00:38:36,580 Because you can work a little bit 945 00:38:36,580 --> 00:38:38,050 overtime or something like that, and some men 946 00:38:38,050 --> 00:38:39,050 did care about the kids. 947 00:38:39,050 --> 00:38:40,805 I'm obviously being facetious. 948 00:38:40,805 --> 00:38:42,930 So it could be, some men were willing to spend time 949 00:38:42,930 --> 00:38:44,260 with their kids, et cetera. 950 00:38:44,260 --> 00:38:48,617 OK, now let's go to the income effect. 951 00:38:48,617 --> 00:38:50,075 For whom is the income effect going 952 00:38:50,075 --> 00:38:54,570 to be bigger, men or women? 953 00:38:54,570 --> 00:38:57,435 For whom is the income effect going to be bigger? 954 00:38:57,435 --> 00:38:58,920 Yeah. 955 00:38:58,920 --> 00:39:00,080 AUDIENCE: Maybe men. 956 00:39:00,080 --> 00:39:01,160 JONATHAN GRUBER: Because? 957 00:39:01,160 --> 00:39:04,410 AUDIENCE: Because they have a goal of like, 958 00:39:04,410 --> 00:39:06,230 they need x amount of money to just provide 959 00:39:06,230 --> 00:39:07,160 for their families. 960 00:39:07,160 --> 00:39:10,310 So if they get this huge raise in wage, 961 00:39:10,310 --> 00:39:12,385 then they become wealthier, and they could start 962 00:39:12,385 --> 00:39:13,820 doing more leisure in the week. 963 00:39:13,820 --> 00:39:15,660 JONATHAN GRUBER: Exactly. 964 00:39:15,660 --> 00:39:17,885 There's actually two reasons it's men. 965 00:39:17,885 --> 00:39:20,010 One, you're more likely to have your target income. 966 00:39:20,010 --> 00:39:24,000 Two is, you can't have an income effect if you don't work. 967 00:39:24,000 --> 00:39:26,160 The income effect is proportional to how hard 968 00:39:26,160 --> 00:39:27,730 you are working. 969 00:39:27,730 --> 00:39:29,580 If you weren't working, then there's 970 00:39:29,580 --> 00:39:30,990 no income effect, right? 971 00:39:30,990 --> 00:39:33,870 Income effect is essentially-- the income effect for labor 972 00:39:33,870 --> 00:39:38,400 is essentially the hours times dH dy. 973 00:39:41,240 --> 00:39:43,120 What Manny said was the reason why 974 00:39:43,120 --> 00:39:45,367 dH dy might be bigger for men than women, 975 00:39:45,367 --> 00:39:46,700 because they have these targets. 976 00:39:46,700 --> 00:39:48,500 More relevantly, if women weren't working, 977 00:39:48,500 --> 00:39:50,042 they didn't have dH, so this is zero. 978 00:39:50,042 --> 00:39:51,530 So the income effect is zero. 979 00:39:51,530 --> 00:39:57,740 So for men, this was big, and for women, this was small, OK? 980 00:39:57,740 --> 00:39:59,720 Put this together, and what does it 981 00:39:59,720 --> 00:40:02,810 suggest about the relative shapes of labor supply for men 982 00:40:02,810 --> 00:40:03,620 and women? 983 00:40:03,620 --> 00:40:05,238 Someone raise their hand and tell me. 984 00:40:05,238 --> 00:40:07,030 What does it suggests what the labor supply 985 00:40:07,030 --> 00:40:09,197 curve would look like for men and women in this era? 986 00:40:14,730 --> 00:40:17,190 OK, given the intuition we talked 987 00:40:17,190 --> 00:40:19,857 about here, what does it suggest the female and male-- 988 00:40:19,857 --> 00:40:22,440 the married women labor supply and the male labor supply curve 989 00:40:22,440 --> 00:40:25,050 should look like? 990 00:40:25,050 --> 00:40:27,680 You guys can get this, come on. 991 00:40:27,680 --> 00:40:29,430 Well, let's talk-- what did we talk about? 992 00:40:29,430 --> 00:40:31,940 We talked about the substitution effect. 993 00:40:31,940 --> 00:40:34,910 If the wage goes up, it leads to more leisure, which means 994 00:40:34,910 --> 00:40:36,910 it leads to more labor supply. 995 00:40:36,910 --> 00:40:38,660 By the income effect, if the wage goes up, 996 00:40:38,660 --> 00:40:41,140 it leads to less labor supply. 997 00:40:41,140 --> 00:40:42,780 So for men, with-- 998 00:40:42,780 --> 00:40:45,810 for women, with a big substitution effect 999 00:40:45,810 --> 00:40:50,160 and a small income effect, this suggests a standard steep 1000 00:40:50,160 --> 00:40:51,150 upward-- 1001 00:40:51,150 --> 00:40:54,700 standard upward-sloping supply curve. 1002 00:40:54,700 --> 00:40:56,350 Think of the income effect being zero. 1003 00:40:56,350 --> 00:40:58,225 Then we get the standard substitution effect. 1004 00:40:58,225 --> 00:40:59,590 We know the sign of that. 1005 00:40:59,590 --> 00:41:02,440 So for women, this suggests an upward-sloping supply curve, 1006 00:41:02,440 --> 00:41:04,270 just like a substitution effect suggests 1007 00:41:04,270 --> 00:41:06,450 a downward-sloping demand curve. 1008 00:41:06,450 --> 00:41:08,860 For men, it's not clear. 1009 00:41:08,860 --> 00:41:11,980 You could very much get a Giffen effect here, 1010 00:41:11,980 --> 00:41:15,010 because basically, there's not much option for substitution, 1011 00:41:15,010 --> 00:41:19,560 but they might work a lot less if they get rich, OK? 1012 00:41:19,560 --> 00:41:21,290 So that is sort of this-- 1013 00:41:21,290 --> 00:41:23,040 what I like with this example-- it's hard, 1014 00:41:23,040 --> 00:41:24,390 but I like that this example sort of illustrates 1015 00:41:24,390 --> 00:41:27,060 how substitution and income effects can come together 1016 00:41:27,060 --> 00:41:29,580 to get a bottom line answer. 1017 00:41:29,580 --> 00:41:31,290 What do we know? 1018 00:41:31,290 --> 00:41:34,810 What we know is that actually, evidence is that female labor 1019 00:41:34,810 --> 00:41:37,712 supply was very elastic, that circa this era, 1020 00:41:37,712 --> 00:41:39,420 female labor supply was in the elasticity 1021 00:41:39,420 --> 00:41:41,610 of between 0.5 and 1. 1022 00:41:41,610 --> 00:41:45,660 That if you raised women's wage by 10%, there was a 5% to 10% 1023 00:41:45,660 --> 00:41:47,400 increase in their labor supply, which 1024 00:41:47,400 --> 00:41:51,900 is pretty not elastic-elastic, but reasonably elastic, OK? 1025 00:41:51,900 --> 00:41:55,760 Whereas for men it was pretty much zero. 1026 00:41:55,760 --> 00:41:56,618 It wasn't negative. 1027 00:41:56,618 --> 00:41:57,410 It wasn't positive. 1028 00:41:57,410 --> 00:41:58,460 It was basically zero. 1029 00:41:58,460 --> 00:42:02,410 Basically, men just worked 40 hours and then went home, OK? 1030 00:42:02,410 --> 00:42:05,890 So basically, in an era where for women, the labor supply was 1031 00:42:05,890 --> 00:42:08,758 very elastic and of the standard direction, 1032 00:42:08,758 --> 00:42:10,300 higher wages lead you to work harder, 1033 00:42:10,300 --> 00:42:12,758 an upward-sloping supply curve. 1034 00:42:12,758 --> 00:42:14,800 But for men, it was pretty much a vertical supply 1035 00:42:14,800 --> 00:42:16,720 curve, maybe even a bit backward bending, 1036 00:42:16,720 --> 00:42:19,240 maybe even a wrong sign supply curve. 1037 00:42:19,240 --> 00:42:22,800 But pretty much, you could think of it as zero, OK? 1038 00:42:22,800 --> 00:42:26,160 Now, what do we think has happened in the 40 years 1039 00:42:26,160 --> 00:42:28,020 since these two numbers? 1040 00:42:28,020 --> 00:42:30,120 So elasticity of woman of between 0.5 and 1, 1041 00:42:30,120 --> 00:42:32,130 and men of zero, what do we think 1042 00:42:32,130 --> 00:42:34,560 has happened to these two numbers in the 40 years 1043 00:42:34,560 --> 00:42:38,850 since these studies, and why? 1044 00:42:38,850 --> 00:42:41,350 What do you think has happened to these elasticity estimates 1045 00:42:41,350 --> 00:42:42,480 and why? 1046 00:42:42,480 --> 00:42:42,980 Yeah. 1047 00:42:42,980 --> 00:42:45,130 AUDIENCE: Are we talking about these together? 1048 00:42:45,130 --> 00:42:45,850 JONATHAN GRUBER: Let's talk about women. 1049 00:42:45,850 --> 00:42:47,764 What do you think has happened to the female estimate? 1050 00:42:47,764 --> 00:42:49,420 AUDIENCE: Probably gotten less elastic. 1051 00:42:49,420 --> 00:42:51,530 JONATHAN GRUBER: Because? 1052 00:42:51,530 --> 00:42:53,742 AUDIENCE: More of them are working in a primary role. 1053 00:42:53,742 --> 00:42:54,700 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 1054 00:42:54,700 --> 00:42:56,075 Well, first of all, this is going 1055 00:42:56,075 --> 00:42:58,840 to come down, because in fact, it's now more standard just 1056 00:42:58,840 --> 00:43:00,460 to work, right? 1057 00:43:00,460 --> 00:43:05,122 In fact, now, for a woman today, in many communities, 1058 00:43:05,122 --> 00:43:06,580 it's like being a man in 70s, which 1059 00:43:06,580 --> 00:43:08,038 is if you don't go to work, there's 1060 00:43:08,038 --> 00:43:10,300 no one to hang out with, OK? 1061 00:43:10,300 --> 00:43:12,190 So basically, this is going to get smaller. 1062 00:43:12,190 --> 00:43:14,315 And they're more of a primary winner in the family. 1063 00:43:14,315 --> 00:43:15,642 This is going to get bigger. 1064 00:43:15,642 --> 00:43:17,600 So in fact, female labor supply has fallen more 1065 00:43:17,600 --> 00:43:19,840 to like about an elasticity about 0.2. 1066 00:43:19,840 --> 00:43:22,930 It's actually fallen over time. 1067 00:43:22,930 --> 00:43:26,460 Now, for men, the question is, do you get the opposite effect? 1068 00:43:26,460 --> 00:43:29,075 Actually, men sort of care more about their kids now, 1069 00:43:29,075 --> 00:43:31,200 and there's more sort of activities going on during 1070 00:43:31,200 --> 00:43:33,500 the day, but in fact it hasn't. 1071 00:43:33,500 --> 00:43:37,410 In fact, male labor supply still is pretty inelastic. 1072 00:43:37,410 --> 00:43:40,690 What's happened is kids are now in childcare. 1073 00:43:40,690 --> 00:43:44,900 So basically, we've gone from a world where, as wages went up, 1074 00:43:44,900 --> 00:43:46,850 women went-- 1075 00:43:46,850 --> 00:43:48,063 men worked. 1076 00:43:48,063 --> 00:43:50,480 Women either worked or didn't work, depending on the wage, 1077 00:43:50,480 --> 00:43:52,438 and if they worked, the kids went in childcare. 1078 00:43:52,438 --> 00:43:55,738 Now men work and women work, and kids are in childcare. 1079 00:43:55,738 --> 00:43:58,280 And that's basically the change, the evolution of the labor-- 1080 00:43:58,280 --> 00:44:00,230 roughly speaking, obviously. 1081 00:44:00,230 --> 00:44:01,970 Still, female labor force participation 1082 00:44:01,970 --> 00:44:03,715 is only about 70%, OK? 1083 00:44:03,715 --> 00:44:05,840 Many women still do stay home and raise their kids, 1084 00:44:05,840 --> 00:44:08,330 and are in and out of the labor force, OK? 1085 00:44:08,330 --> 00:44:09,900 But by and large, we moved to a world 1086 00:44:09,900 --> 00:44:12,870 with just overall less elastic labor supply. 1087 00:44:12,870 --> 00:44:13,922 Yeah. 1088 00:44:13,922 --> 00:44:18,740 AUDIENCE: Between the average two-income household is richer 1089 00:44:18,740 --> 00:44:19,370 now, or-- 1090 00:44:19,370 --> 00:44:19,690 JONATHAN GRUBER: No. 1091 00:44:19,690 --> 00:44:20,770 The average-- well, OK, we're going 1092 00:44:20,770 --> 00:44:23,360 to get into this when we talk about income distribution. 1093 00:44:23,360 --> 00:44:25,527 What this has done is allowed the average two-family 1094 00:44:25,527 --> 00:44:27,022 household to tread water. 1095 00:44:27,022 --> 00:44:28,730 So it's, the average two-family household 1096 00:44:28,730 --> 00:44:31,440 today has the same income as they did in the 1970s. 1097 00:44:31,440 --> 00:44:31,940 Why? 1098 00:44:31,940 --> 00:44:34,965 Because workers earn a ton less in real terms than they did, 1099 00:44:34,965 --> 00:44:36,590 and that's facts about inequality we'll 1100 00:44:36,590 --> 00:44:38,450 come to, that basically, the average family 1101 00:44:38,450 --> 00:44:40,165 in America, despite having-- 1102 00:44:40,165 --> 00:44:42,290 going from the wife not working to the wife working 1103 00:44:42,290 --> 00:44:44,570 is no better off they were 40 years ago. 1104 00:44:44,570 --> 00:44:47,990 And that has lots implications we'll talk about, OK? 1105 00:44:47,990 --> 00:44:50,880 So any other questions about that? 1106 00:44:50,880 --> 00:44:55,640 So let me end with one final example, an application, OK? 1107 00:44:55,640 --> 00:45:01,868 Which is to the problem we have in the world of child labor. 1108 00:45:01,868 --> 00:45:03,410 It's a huge problem around the world, 1109 00:45:03,410 --> 00:45:05,180 is kids being forced to work. 1110 00:45:05,180 --> 00:45:07,430 It was a huge problem in the US till the 20th century. 1111 00:45:07,430 --> 00:45:08,972 It's a huge problem around the world, 1112 00:45:08,972 --> 00:45:11,180 because A, work can often be dangerous and bad 1113 00:45:11,180 --> 00:45:14,120 for their health, but B, they can't be going to school 1114 00:45:14,120 --> 00:45:16,010 and having the opportunity better themselves. 1115 00:45:16,010 --> 00:45:18,170 If a kid is spending all day working, 1116 00:45:18,170 --> 00:45:19,670 then that kid is destined to a life 1117 00:45:19,670 --> 00:45:21,920 of working in the same crappy job, 1118 00:45:21,920 --> 00:45:24,110 because there's no way to get the skills that allows 1119 00:45:24,110 --> 00:45:27,220 them to grow and go further. 1120 00:45:27,220 --> 00:45:31,630 Now, one-- we will talk in the next few lectures-- in a few 1121 00:45:31,630 --> 00:45:34,450 lectures about international trade. 1122 00:45:34,450 --> 00:45:36,820 And one criticism of international trade 1123 00:45:36,820 --> 00:45:39,490 is people say, "Well, if you allow these developing 1124 00:45:39,490 --> 00:45:43,000 countries to sell more stuff to the developed world, 1125 00:45:43,000 --> 00:45:45,520 that will-- they'll put the kids to work more." 1126 00:45:45,520 --> 00:45:48,415 So if we have free trade and Vietnam can suddenly sell 1127 00:45:48,415 --> 00:45:51,040 a bunch stuff to America, that's more kids they;re going to put 1128 00:45:51,040 --> 00:45:52,750 to work making that stuff. 1129 00:45:52,750 --> 00:45:55,750 So one common argument you hear against free trade 1130 00:45:55,750 --> 00:46:00,700 is it's bad for kids, but in fact, that argument is not 1131 00:46:00,700 --> 00:46:04,800 necessarily right, because it ignores an important point. 1132 00:46:04,800 --> 00:46:05,550 Manny? 1133 00:46:05,550 --> 00:46:10,680 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE] 1134 00:46:10,680 --> 00:46:12,600 JONATHAN GRUBER: No, that's a different issue. 1135 00:46:12,600 --> 00:46:15,360 The point-- that's right, but the point it ignores 1136 00:46:15,360 --> 00:46:17,435 is free trade makes families richer. 1137 00:46:17,435 --> 00:46:18,810 And the families are richer, they 1138 00:46:18,810 --> 00:46:22,320 may want to buy more education for their kids. 1139 00:46:22,320 --> 00:46:23,730 So on the one hand, it's true. 1140 00:46:23,730 --> 00:46:26,942 Free trade makes kids more valuable in the labor force. 1141 00:46:26,942 --> 00:46:28,650 On the other hand, it makes family richer 1142 00:46:28,650 --> 00:46:30,700 and they want more education for their kids. 1143 00:46:30,700 --> 00:46:32,492 So to look at that two Dartmouth professors 1144 00:46:32,492 --> 00:46:34,303 did a study, who looked at Vietnam, 1145 00:46:34,303 --> 00:46:36,720 and looked at what happened when Vietnam liberalized trade 1146 00:46:36,720 --> 00:46:37,870 in rice. 1147 00:46:37,870 --> 00:46:40,192 So let's go to figure 15-6. 1148 00:46:40,192 --> 00:46:42,150 Now, we haven't gotten international trade yet, 1149 00:46:42,150 --> 00:46:44,310 so I'm just going to sort of hand wave through this. 1150 00:46:44,310 --> 00:46:45,570 You don't need to really understand this graph, 1151 00:46:45,570 --> 00:46:47,150 except what the bottom line is. 1152 00:46:47,150 --> 00:46:52,040 OK, what happened was before trade liberalization 1153 00:46:52,040 --> 00:46:55,610 of Vietnam, before 1989, you could only 1154 00:46:55,610 --> 00:46:58,840 sell rice made in Vietnam in Vietnam. 1155 00:46:58,840 --> 00:47:00,570 So what that meant was the supply of rice 1156 00:47:00,570 --> 00:47:04,320 was s sub v. The demand for rice was d sub v, 1157 00:47:04,320 --> 00:47:06,810 and the amount of rice sold was q sub v. And kids 1158 00:47:06,810 --> 00:47:08,930 worked in the rice paddies. 1159 00:47:08,930 --> 00:47:11,870 When they liberalized trade, suddenly Vietnam 1160 00:47:11,870 --> 00:47:14,090 could sell to a much larger market. 1161 00:47:14,090 --> 00:47:18,030 They could sell to the world market, d sub w. 1162 00:47:18,030 --> 00:47:19,830 That's a bigger market. 1163 00:47:19,830 --> 00:47:23,010 So they were able to shift up their supply curve 1164 00:47:23,010 --> 00:47:24,210 and sell more rice. 1165 00:47:26,693 --> 00:47:28,610 They could sell more rice, because now they're 1166 00:47:28,610 --> 00:47:31,110 selling to the whole world, not just to Vietnam. 1167 00:47:31,110 --> 00:47:33,050 You don't need to notice this in the graph so much intuition. 1168 00:47:33,050 --> 00:47:34,550 If you give someone a bigger market, 1169 00:47:34,550 --> 00:47:36,350 they're going to make more stuff, OK? 1170 00:47:36,350 --> 00:47:36,990 Yeah. 1171 00:47:36,990 --> 00:47:39,282 AUDIENCE: But doesn't that also put them in competition 1172 00:47:39,282 --> 00:47:41,357 in other countries, whereas if it was just like-- 1173 00:47:41,357 --> 00:47:43,190 if each country is just selling to themself, 1174 00:47:43,190 --> 00:47:45,127 then Vietnam would have-- 1175 00:47:45,127 --> 00:47:47,210 JONATHAN GRUBER: No, they liberalized in the sense 1176 00:47:47,210 --> 00:47:48,820 that they let it send out. 1177 00:47:48,820 --> 00:47:50,196 I didn't say they let more in. 1178 00:47:50,196 --> 00:47:50,970 AUDIENCE: Oh. 1179 00:47:50,970 --> 00:47:51,710 JONATHAN GRUBER: OK, but we'll come back 1180 00:47:51,710 --> 00:47:53,480 to international trade, OK? 1181 00:47:53,480 --> 00:47:55,760 So basically, the point is, there 1182 00:47:55,760 --> 00:47:59,130 was this demand shock that allowed them to sell more rice. 1183 00:47:59,130 --> 00:48:01,938 So what effect does that have on the market for child labor? 1184 00:48:01,938 --> 00:48:03,855 Let's go to the highly complicated last figure 1185 00:48:03,855 --> 00:48:06,140 and let me walk you through this. 1186 00:48:06,140 --> 00:48:09,980 Here is the market for child labor, OK? 1187 00:48:09,980 --> 00:48:12,980 On the x-axis is the amount of child labor. 1188 00:48:12,980 --> 00:48:16,430 On the y-axis the wage of kids, OK? 1189 00:48:16,430 --> 00:48:21,430 We start at point one, initial demand and initial supply, 1190 00:48:21,430 --> 00:48:23,210 wage 1, L1. 1191 00:48:23,210 --> 00:48:26,840 Now we liberalize trade, and that 1192 00:48:26,840 --> 00:48:29,480 leads to more demand for child labor, 1193 00:48:29,480 --> 00:48:32,500 because we want to produce more rice. 1194 00:48:32,500 --> 00:48:36,210 So that shifts us out to D2 and point two. 1195 00:48:36,210 --> 00:48:37,680 So we have more child labor. 1196 00:48:37,680 --> 00:48:39,840 That's bad. 1197 00:48:39,840 --> 00:48:44,400 But what this ignores is families are now richer, 1198 00:48:44,400 --> 00:48:48,750 and with the income effect, they will buy their kids education. 1199 00:48:48,750 --> 00:48:52,520 They'll pull their kids out of working and put them in school. 1200 00:48:52,520 --> 00:48:57,580 That's represented as a shift to the left of the supply curve. 1201 00:48:57,580 --> 00:48:59,660 So we move from point two to point three 1202 00:48:59,660 --> 00:49:01,390 through the income effect. 1203 00:49:01,390 --> 00:49:02,620 Families are now richer. 1204 00:49:02,620 --> 00:49:05,600 And indeed, if the income effect is large enough, 1205 00:49:05,600 --> 00:49:07,920 you could move to point four. 1206 00:49:07,920 --> 00:49:11,360 You could actually have a reduction in child labor. 1207 00:49:11,360 --> 00:49:12,260 Why? 1208 00:49:12,260 --> 00:49:14,420 Because the benefits of more kids working 1209 00:49:14,420 --> 00:49:16,310 in terms of producing more rice is 1210 00:49:16,310 --> 00:49:18,982 exceeded by the value of the firms of taking-- 1211 00:49:18,982 --> 00:49:20,690 of the families of taking the extra money 1212 00:49:20,690 --> 00:49:24,930 they're making and putting it into education for their kids. 1213 00:49:24,930 --> 00:49:28,560 And in fact, the studies showed that we did move to a point 1214 00:49:28,560 --> 00:49:31,230 like point four, OK? 1215 00:49:31,230 --> 00:49:33,870 We actually found that child labor 1216 00:49:33,870 --> 00:49:37,280 fell when they liberalized trade, 1217 00:49:37,280 --> 00:49:40,220 that the intuitive argument, that gee, if they 1218 00:49:40,220 --> 00:49:42,950 sell more, more kids are going to work, it's wrong. 1219 00:49:42,950 --> 00:49:46,230 That in fact, when you sell more, yes, more kids-- demand 1220 00:49:46,230 --> 00:49:48,530 for more kids, but families are so rich, 1221 00:49:48,530 --> 00:49:52,410 they put their kids in education rather than their fields, OK? 1222 00:49:52,410 --> 00:49:55,230 And that is a wonderful sort of counterintuitive story 1223 00:49:55,230 --> 00:49:56,310 of how what-- 1224 00:49:56,310 --> 00:49:58,292 I'll talk about economies like free trade, how 1225 00:49:58,292 --> 00:50:00,750 free trade can actually have an unexpected positive effect. 1226 00:50:00,750 --> 00:50:01,940 We might think it's negative. 1227 00:50:01,940 --> 00:50:02,670 And there's a question. 1228 00:50:02,670 --> 00:50:04,920 Come up if you want to talk, but we've got to end now. 1229 00:50:04,920 --> 00:50:06,720 So thank you for saying a minute extra, 1230 00:50:06,720 --> 00:50:11,240 and I will see you guys on Wednesday.