1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:01,960 [SQUEAKING] 2 00:00:01,960 --> 00:00:03,920 [RUSTLING] 3 00:00:03,920 --> 00:00:06,370 [CLICKING] 4 00:00:12,270 --> 00:00:15,342 JONATHAN GRUBER: OK, so let's continue 5 00:00:15,342 --> 00:00:16,550 our discussion of monopolies. 6 00:00:16,550 --> 00:00:18,740 Last time, we talked about monopolies 7 00:00:18,740 --> 00:00:22,670 and talked about how they're another extreme of the market 8 00:00:22,670 --> 00:00:23,750 structure spectrum. 9 00:00:23,750 --> 00:00:25,850 We have perfectly competitive firms, 10 00:00:25,850 --> 00:00:29,150 where there's facing a perfectly elastic demand curve, 11 00:00:29,150 --> 00:00:31,910 and competing with essentially infinite number of other firms 12 00:00:31,910 --> 00:00:35,960 and taking prices, versus a monopolist who owns the market 13 00:00:35,960 --> 00:00:38,000 and sets the price, but therefore, 14 00:00:38,000 --> 00:00:40,790 faces this poisoning effect, which 15 00:00:40,790 --> 00:00:44,583 leads them to under-produce and creates deadweight loss. 16 00:00:44,583 --> 00:00:47,000 So today, we want to continue our discussion of monopolies 17 00:00:47,000 --> 00:00:49,610 with three sort of separate topics. 18 00:00:49,610 --> 00:00:51,380 OK, the first topic I want to cover 19 00:00:51,380 --> 00:00:54,260 is, where do monopolies come from? 20 00:00:54,260 --> 00:00:57,140 So the stork does not bring monopolies. 21 00:00:57,140 --> 00:01:00,200 They come from somewhere else. 22 00:01:00,200 --> 00:01:02,000 So sort of, how do monopolies arise? 23 00:01:08,330 --> 00:01:10,490 And there's really two sources of monopoly 24 00:01:10,490 --> 00:01:12,480 that I want to focus on today. 25 00:01:12,480 --> 00:01:17,030 The first is monopolies that arise 26 00:01:17,030 --> 00:01:23,940 from cost advantages, the monopolies that 27 00:01:23,940 --> 00:01:25,940 arise from cost advantages. 28 00:01:25,940 --> 00:01:29,080 So some markets come with a natural built-in cost 29 00:01:29,080 --> 00:01:31,738 advantage for one participant. 30 00:01:31,738 --> 00:01:34,030 So it could be there's an essential input, like there's 31 00:01:34,030 --> 00:01:36,690 one rock quarry in town. 32 00:01:36,690 --> 00:01:38,380 And whoever controls the rock quarry, 33 00:01:38,380 --> 00:01:42,220 they supply the rocks for the whole area. 34 00:01:42,220 --> 00:01:45,700 In that case, we say that this is an example 35 00:01:45,700 --> 00:01:48,550 of a natural monopoly. 36 00:01:54,130 --> 00:01:59,620 A natural monopoly is a market where, 37 00:01:59,620 --> 00:02:05,370 for all relevant quantities, one firm can always 38 00:02:05,370 --> 00:02:10,840 produce at a lower average cost than another firm can. 39 00:02:10,840 --> 00:02:13,870 So for all relevant quantities, one firm 40 00:02:13,870 --> 00:02:16,120 can always produce at a lower average 41 00:02:16,120 --> 00:02:19,650 cost than can other firms. 42 00:02:19,650 --> 00:02:23,530 OK, this basically is the same as saying 43 00:02:23,530 --> 00:02:27,580 that it's a market where average cost is everywhere declining, 44 00:02:27,580 --> 00:02:30,520 at least in the relevant production range. 45 00:02:30,520 --> 00:02:32,860 You can imagine where, so for some crazy quantities, 46 00:02:32,860 --> 00:02:34,300 average cost increases. 47 00:02:34,300 --> 00:02:37,820 But where average costs is everywhere declining 48 00:02:37,820 --> 00:02:40,557 is a market with a natural monopoly. 49 00:02:40,557 --> 00:02:41,640 So why would this be true? 50 00:02:41,640 --> 00:02:43,682 Let's consider what I think is the simplest case. 51 00:02:43,682 --> 00:02:45,170 Let's think about a water utility, 52 00:02:45,170 --> 00:02:46,760 delivering water to people's houses 53 00:02:46,760 --> 00:02:49,400 through pipes underground. 54 00:02:49,400 --> 00:02:55,980 Once those pipes are laid, it is that the giant fixed costs 55 00:02:55,980 --> 00:02:58,330 are paid, and the marginal costs are trivial. 56 00:02:58,330 --> 00:03:00,120 It's the cost of the water. 57 00:03:00,120 --> 00:03:05,310 The fixed costs are so large relative to the marginal costs 58 00:03:05,310 --> 00:03:07,842 that average cost always declines. 59 00:03:07,842 --> 00:03:09,300 In our typical production function, 60 00:03:09,300 --> 00:03:12,060 remember, average cost first declines, then goes back up. 61 00:03:12,060 --> 00:03:14,460 It first declines, you pay off the fixed costs, 62 00:03:14,460 --> 00:03:16,920 then back up as the rising marginal costs start 63 00:03:16,920 --> 00:03:17,638 to dominate. 64 00:03:17,638 --> 00:03:19,680 This is a market where that second purchase never 65 00:03:19,680 --> 00:03:24,690 gets big enough, say where, essentially, 66 00:03:24,690 --> 00:03:26,700 marginal productivity is close to flat, 67 00:03:26,700 --> 00:03:30,060 so the marginal cost curve isn't rising that fast, and/or 68 00:03:30,060 --> 00:03:33,600 the fixed costs are enormous. 69 00:03:33,600 --> 00:03:36,780 So we could see that in figure 12.1. 70 00:03:36,780 --> 00:03:42,065 Imagine a water utility, which has roughly flat marginal cost. 71 00:03:42,065 --> 00:03:44,190 That is, the marginal cost is the cost of procuring 72 00:03:44,190 --> 00:03:45,780 another gallon of water. 73 00:03:45,780 --> 00:03:47,850 Now once again, at some point, if you 74 00:03:47,850 --> 00:03:49,350 want to give every person in America 75 00:03:49,350 --> 00:03:51,840 one million gallons of water, marginal costs 76 00:03:51,840 --> 00:03:53,040 would start to rise. 77 00:03:53,040 --> 00:03:56,140 But for the relevant range, it's roughly flat. 78 00:03:56,140 --> 00:03:57,700 And yet there's enormous fixed costs. 79 00:03:57,700 --> 00:04:00,290 You got to lay those water pipes. 80 00:04:00,290 --> 00:04:05,780 So in that world, average cost is everywhere declining. 81 00:04:05,780 --> 00:04:07,850 It's approaching marginal cost, but it never 82 00:04:07,850 --> 00:04:09,140 crosses marginal cost. 83 00:04:12,060 --> 00:04:15,300 In such a world, once one firm has 84 00:04:15,300 --> 00:04:17,459 laid the pipes that's providing water, 85 00:04:17,459 --> 00:04:21,279 it never makes sense for another firm to enter. 86 00:04:21,279 --> 00:04:22,750 Entry never makes sense. 87 00:04:22,750 --> 00:04:23,680 Why is that? 88 00:04:23,680 --> 00:04:26,690 Because if another firm thinks about entering, 89 00:04:26,690 --> 00:04:29,120 they can say, oh, look this water utility is making all 90 00:04:29,120 --> 00:04:31,412 this money, this is a great market to enter-- remember, 91 00:04:31,412 --> 00:04:33,170 we talked about unlimited entry and exit 92 00:04:33,170 --> 00:04:35,340 and perfect competition that drives profits away. 93 00:04:35,340 --> 00:04:37,840 Well, let's say another firm says, look at all this profits, 94 00:04:37,840 --> 00:04:38,840 I want into this market. 95 00:04:38,840 --> 00:04:40,215 The first firm will say, I'm just 96 00:04:40,215 --> 00:04:42,690 going to tell you right now, if you enter this market, 97 00:04:42,690 --> 00:04:47,330 I will price at marginal cost until you leave. 98 00:04:47,330 --> 00:04:48,788 For the first firm, they've already 99 00:04:48,788 --> 00:04:50,372 paid to lay down the pipes, so as long 100 00:04:50,372 --> 00:04:53,000 as they're pricing at marginal cost, they're not losing money. 101 00:04:53,000 --> 00:04:57,720 But for the second firm, they will lose money 102 00:04:57,720 --> 00:04:59,310 if the firm stays at marginal cost. 103 00:04:59,310 --> 00:05:01,140 So they'll just never enter. 104 00:05:01,140 --> 00:05:05,250 Because they know the first firm has a barrier to entry. 105 00:05:05,250 --> 00:05:08,990 They have a natural monopoly, having laid down those pipes. 106 00:05:08,990 --> 00:05:13,140 Having already paid that fixed cost, that sunk, 107 00:05:13,140 --> 00:05:14,730 they will win any battle. 108 00:05:14,730 --> 00:05:17,130 They'll just price at or near marginal cost 109 00:05:17,130 --> 00:05:20,550 and drive any competitors out of the market. 110 00:05:20,550 --> 00:05:24,840 So these kinds of essentially natural monopolies 111 00:05:24,840 --> 00:05:31,300 arise when enormous fixed costs create a barrier to entry 112 00:05:31,300 --> 00:05:34,130 when enormous fixed costs create a barrier to entry. 113 00:05:34,130 --> 00:05:37,480 You can see natural monopoly. 114 00:05:37,480 --> 00:05:41,310 And that's one common way monopolies arise in the world. 115 00:05:41,310 --> 00:05:42,740 Think of utilities. 116 00:05:42,740 --> 00:05:45,820 Delivering water is a classic example of that. 117 00:05:45,820 --> 00:05:47,680 That's one way we get monopolies. 118 00:05:47,680 --> 00:05:52,030 The second way we get monopolies is through government action. 119 00:05:55,380 --> 00:05:59,190 Governments also create monopolies remember, 120 00:05:59,190 --> 00:06:02,010 today I told you we talk about governments as good guys. 121 00:06:02,010 --> 00:06:06,390 But still governments can do things which 122 00:06:06,390 --> 00:06:09,270 can create deadweight loss. 123 00:06:09,270 --> 00:06:12,030 And now sometimes, governments do 124 00:06:12,030 --> 00:06:15,060 this for a good reason, like a natural monopoly reason, 125 00:06:15,060 --> 00:06:17,340 like the postal service for example. 126 00:06:17,340 --> 00:06:21,938 Local postal delivery, delivering letters locally, 127 00:06:21,938 --> 00:06:23,730 has all the features of a natural monopoly. 128 00:06:23,730 --> 00:06:25,920 It's a huge fixed cost of building all the post 129 00:06:25,920 --> 00:06:28,740 offices and a small marginal cost of transmitting letters 130 00:06:28,740 --> 00:06:31,470 from place to place. 131 00:06:31,470 --> 00:06:35,030 Now however, in other cases, this is not necessarily true. 132 00:06:35,030 --> 00:06:38,353 In the US, we have very few government-created monopolies. 133 00:06:38,353 --> 00:06:40,520 The rest of the world, especially in the developing, 134 00:06:40,520 --> 00:06:41,860 it's much more common. 135 00:06:41,860 --> 00:06:43,610 Many countries have the government control 136 00:06:43,610 --> 00:06:47,690 the production of steel, the airlines are controlled 137 00:06:47,690 --> 00:06:50,240 by the government , banking is often controlled 138 00:06:50,240 --> 00:06:51,360 by the government. 139 00:06:51,360 --> 00:06:53,490 These are places where probably evidence suggests 140 00:06:53,490 --> 00:06:55,340 it would be more efficient to not have the government control 141 00:06:55,340 --> 00:06:55,940 this. 142 00:06:55,940 --> 00:06:58,930 There is no real natural monopoly in banking. 143 00:06:58,930 --> 00:07:01,700 But it's more for political reasons that they're created. 144 00:07:01,700 --> 00:07:03,970 But that's not really that relevant in the US. 145 00:07:03,970 --> 00:07:05,950 Even the post office isn't a monopoly anymore, 146 00:07:05,950 --> 00:07:09,370 with FedEx and UPS and stuff. 147 00:07:09,370 --> 00:07:12,580 So it's not really relevant in the US. 148 00:07:12,580 --> 00:07:16,630 The more relevant for the US, way that the government creates 149 00:07:16,630 --> 00:07:20,290 monopoly is by creating barriers to entry. 150 00:07:20,290 --> 00:07:21,790 The government could create barriers 151 00:07:21,790 --> 00:07:24,685 to entry, the most prominent of which is patents. 152 00:07:27,808 --> 00:07:32,550 The most prominent barrier to entry is a patent. 153 00:07:32,550 --> 00:07:34,470 This is the case where the fixed cost here 154 00:07:34,470 --> 00:07:35,770 isn't building a pipe. 155 00:07:35,770 --> 00:07:38,610 It's coming up with an idea. 156 00:07:38,610 --> 00:07:41,340 And that basically the government 157 00:07:41,340 --> 00:07:45,030 has a law which says that, if you have a new idea 158 00:07:45,030 --> 00:07:49,010 and you patent it, you are granted a monopoly 159 00:07:49,010 --> 00:07:51,290 to sell the resulting good for 20 160 00:07:51,290 --> 00:07:54,630 years from the date of patent. 161 00:07:54,630 --> 00:07:57,610 So when you patent a good, you're 162 00:07:57,610 --> 00:08:01,380 granted the right to a monopoly over that market for 20 years. 163 00:08:01,380 --> 00:08:03,720 Essentially, the government is creating a monopoly. 164 00:08:03,720 --> 00:08:06,180 It's saying, once you've patented that-- 165 00:08:06,180 --> 00:08:08,250 now remember, very importantly-- especially 166 00:08:08,250 --> 00:08:10,425 for drug development-- it's not the date at which 167 00:08:10,425 --> 00:08:11,820 the good comes to market. 168 00:08:11,820 --> 00:08:13,800 It's the data at which you file. 169 00:08:13,800 --> 00:08:15,990 So if you file for a patent and it takes you 170 00:08:15,990 --> 00:08:17,910 19 years to develop the product, then you only 171 00:08:17,910 --> 00:08:19,930 get one year monopoly in the market. 172 00:08:19,930 --> 00:08:20,810 So it's the sum. 173 00:08:20,810 --> 00:08:23,352 20 years is both the development period and the sales period. 174 00:08:23,352 --> 00:08:26,310 You get 20 years from the date you file. 175 00:08:26,310 --> 00:08:29,550 Now, patents are quite interesting because the welfare 176 00:08:29,550 --> 00:08:32,470 implications are kind of mixed. 177 00:08:32,470 --> 00:08:37,919 On the one hand, a patent, by creating monopoly, 178 00:08:37,919 --> 00:08:39,990 creates deadweight loss. 179 00:08:39,990 --> 00:08:43,770 For potentially up to 20 years, you've 180 00:08:43,770 --> 00:08:45,715 got deadweight loss in that market, 181 00:08:45,715 --> 00:08:47,340 because one firm has the monopoly right 182 00:08:47,340 --> 00:08:49,860 to sell the good. 183 00:08:49,860 --> 00:08:54,360 On the other hand, why might patents be a good idea. 184 00:08:54,360 --> 00:08:55,023 Yeah. 185 00:08:55,023 --> 00:08:57,405 AUDIENCE: [INAUDIBLE] for developing drugs, 186 00:08:57,405 --> 00:08:59,905 the company that can't ever make any money off 187 00:08:59,905 --> 00:09:01,820 of its research and development costs 188 00:09:01,820 --> 00:09:05,262 will never be incentivized to develop it [INAUDIBLE].. 189 00:09:05,262 --> 00:09:06,220 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 190 00:09:06,220 --> 00:09:11,050 Because research and development is a huge fixed cost. 191 00:09:11,050 --> 00:09:12,550 And if you pay that huge fixed cost, 192 00:09:12,550 --> 00:09:15,160 and the minute you develop it someone else can just copy you, 193 00:09:15,160 --> 00:09:17,320 then you'd never invest those fixed costs. 194 00:09:21,370 --> 00:09:23,860 We'll talk later in the course about externalities. 195 00:09:23,860 --> 00:09:27,700 But you think of this as sort of a positive spillover 196 00:09:27,700 --> 00:09:34,700 from R&D. When firms do R&D, when a firm invents something, 197 00:09:34,700 --> 00:09:38,970 it benefits everybody who might produce that good. 198 00:09:38,970 --> 00:09:41,540 So if I invent something, then everybody could copy me, 199 00:09:41,540 --> 00:09:42,770 could benefit. 200 00:09:42,770 --> 00:09:45,215 So I will not invest in R&D unless I 201 00:09:45,215 --> 00:09:47,090 can be sure I might get some money out of it. 202 00:09:47,090 --> 00:09:49,130 And that's what the patent does. 203 00:09:49,130 --> 00:09:51,920 It reduces those spillovers by saying, OK, 204 00:09:51,920 --> 00:09:54,620 you get to own this for 20 years and make some money on it. 205 00:09:54,620 --> 00:09:56,870 Therefore, go ahead and invest. 206 00:09:56,870 --> 00:09:59,210 In other words, what a patent does 207 00:09:59,210 --> 00:10:02,500 is, essentially, the government's saying, 208 00:10:02,500 --> 00:10:05,460 you're going to get a reward for being first to market. 209 00:10:05,460 --> 00:10:08,780 And that reward is 20 years of privilege of being 210 00:10:08,780 --> 00:10:09,917 a monopolist in a market. 211 00:10:09,917 --> 00:10:12,250 Therefore, that's an incentive for you to go and invent. 212 00:10:12,250 --> 00:10:12,900 Yeah. 213 00:10:12,900 --> 00:10:15,400 AUDIENCE: What's the process like for extending your patent? 214 00:10:15,400 --> 00:10:16,977 Because I know Disney, for example, 215 00:10:16,977 --> 00:10:20,050 has [INAUDIBLE] which is giving them 216 00:10:20,050 --> 00:10:22,040 more years than what they had? 217 00:10:22,040 --> 00:10:23,095 JONATHAN GRUBER: That's a very detailed concept 218 00:10:23,095 --> 00:10:24,560 that I don't have enough time to get into, 219 00:10:24,560 --> 00:10:26,910 but there's a whole bunch of legal battles around that. 220 00:10:26,910 --> 00:10:30,440 But the bottom line is, there's a patent tradeoff here. 221 00:10:30,440 --> 00:10:34,100 The tradeoff is, on the one hand, 222 00:10:34,100 --> 00:10:36,700 it's what we call a static versus dynamic tradeoff, sort 223 00:10:36,700 --> 00:10:38,350 of today versus the future. 224 00:10:38,350 --> 00:10:41,650 At any point in time, there's a ton of deadweight loss 225 00:10:41,650 --> 00:10:44,080 out there, because monopolists who have patents 226 00:10:44,080 --> 00:10:46,830 are under-producing. 227 00:10:46,830 --> 00:10:50,700 At the same time, over time, we're 228 00:10:50,700 --> 00:10:53,290 getting cool new products because of patents. 229 00:10:53,290 --> 00:10:55,950 And that's the tradeoff. 230 00:10:55,950 --> 00:10:57,870 How did 20 years get picked? 231 00:10:57,870 --> 00:10:59,700 Ideally, you'd have some optimal period 232 00:10:59,700 --> 00:11:02,520 to resolve that tradeoff, the ultimate result of a tradeoff 233 00:11:02,520 --> 00:11:05,448 long enough to get creation, but short enough so 234 00:11:05,448 --> 00:11:06,990 that the gains on that creation don't 235 00:11:06,990 --> 00:11:10,140 exceed the deadweight loss from monopoly. 236 00:11:10,140 --> 00:11:11,910 And that's an example how a monopoly can 237 00:11:11,910 --> 00:11:13,680 arise from a government action. 238 00:11:13,680 --> 00:11:17,700 And the point is that, for both natural monopolies and patents, 239 00:11:17,700 --> 00:11:20,890 there are legitimate reasons for monopolies to arise. 240 00:11:20,890 --> 00:11:24,240 So what I want to say is, monopolies are not bad. 241 00:11:24,240 --> 00:11:29,200 They're not necessarily an inherent flaw in the system. 242 00:11:29,200 --> 00:11:31,200 There are legitimate reasons to have monopolies, 243 00:11:31,200 --> 00:11:34,470 both because of natural monopoly and because of patent. 244 00:11:34,470 --> 00:11:38,960 But they do, at any point in time, create deadweight loss. 245 00:11:38,960 --> 00:11:39,830 Yeah. 246 00:11:39,830 --> 00:11:43,580 AUDIENCE: Is there a way to measure 247 00:11:43,580 --> 00:11:48,475 how the impact of [INAUDIBLE] something that receives patent, 248 00:11:48,475 --> 00:11:51,580 like how [INAUDIBLE] that relates to the deadweight loss 249 00:11:51,580 --> 00:11:52,080 [INAUDIBLE]? 250 00:11:52,080 --> 00:11:52,960 JONATHAN GRUBER: It's a great question. 251 00:11:52,960 --> 00:11:55,350 There are people who do spend their lives doing that. 252 00:11:55,350 --> 00:11:59,760 And basically, the way you would do 253 00:11:59,760 --> 00:12:02,190 it is you would essentially measure the consumer 254 00:12:02,190 --> 00:12:04,950 surplus created from the new good, versus-- it 255 00:12:04,950 --> 00:12:06,120 would be the triangle sizes. 256 00:12:06,120 --> 00:12:07,345 It would be, how much consumer surplus would 257 00:12:07,345 --> 00:12:08,730 you get from the new good versus deadweight loss 258 00:12:08,730 --> 00:12:10,500 from that good sales being restricted. 259 00:12:10,500 --> 00:12:11,917 Now obviously, if it's a good that 260 00:12:11,917 --> 00:12:14,160 never would have existed otherwise, by definition, 261 00:12:14,160 --> 00:12:15,445 the patent's a good thing. 262 00:12:15,445 --> 00:12:17,070 Because who cares about deadweight loss 263 00:12:17,070 --> 00:12:19,153 if you never would have had it in the first place. 264 00:12:19,153 --> 00:12:21,390 The question really is about the substitutability. 265 00:12:21,390 --> 00:12:23,010 If you're patenting something which 266 00:12:23,010 --> 00:12:26,650 is only incrementally better, then maybe it's not worth it. 267 00:12:26,650 --> 00:12:29,470 So that's sort of the tradeoff. 268 00:12:29,470 --> 00:12:31,770 Other questions? 269 00:12:31,770 --> 00:12:39,610 OK, so now let's talk about addressing or regulating 270 00:12:39,610 --> 00:12:40,360 monopolies. 271 00:12:43,540 --> 00:12:46,450 Let's go back to think about our natural monopoly case. 272 00:12:50,410 --> 00:12:52,960 Let's think about our natural monopoly case. 273 00:12:54,787 --> 00:12:57,120 Actually, I'm going to call this section not regulating. 274 00:12:57,120 --> 00:12:59,380 I'm going to call this addressing monopolies, 275 00:12:59,380 --> 00:13:02,400 addressing monopolies. 276 00:13:02,400 --> 00:13:05,520 There are different ways that we can address monopolies. 277 00:13:05,520 --> 00:13:09,310 And we'll go back to our natural monopoly case to make it easy. 278 00:13:09,310 --> 00:13:11,680 The first way we can address monopoly 279 00:13:11,680 --> 00:13:15,740 is through government regulation. 280 00:13:15,740 --> 00:13:16,760 So let's step back here. 281 00:13:16,760 --> 00:13:19,680 The bottom line is, we have a monopoly that should exist, 282 00:13:19,680 --> 00:13:22,021 say a natural monopoly. 283 00:13:22,021 --> 00:13:23,620 It exists naturally. 284 00:13:23,620 --> 00:13:27,250 At the same time, that is creating a deadweight loss. 285 00:13:27,250 --> 00:13:29,390 It's creating inefficiency. 286 00:13:29,390 --> 00:13:31,640 So the brilliance, the insight of 287 00:13:31,640 --> 00:13:33,950 the first fundamental theorem of all for economics 288 00:13:33,950 --> 00:13:36,317 was, the competition through entry and exit 289 00:13:36,317 --> 00:13:38,150 will bring us the efficient production level 290 00:13:38,150 --> 00:13:40,560 and reduce deadweight loss. 291 00:13:40,560 --> 00:13:42,840 Here with a natural monopoly, that doesn't work. 292 00:13:42,840 --> 00:13:45,010 Competition can't work, therefore, 293 00:13:45,010 --> 00:13:46,770 we end up with a deadweight loss, 294 00:13:46,770 --> 00:13:49,420 because the firm that owns the market is under-producing. 295 00:13:52,120 --> 00:13:54,880 This is the first case, as I mentioned last time, of what we 296 00:13:54,880 --> 00:13:57,660 call a market failure. 297 00:13:57,660 --> 00:14:01,520 The market outcome is not delivering 298 00:14:01,520 --> 00:14:05,810 the welfare-maximizing result. And once there's 299 00:14:05,810 --> 00:14:08,540 a market failure, there is a potential beneficial role 300 00:14:08,540 --> 00:14:09,610 for government. 301 00:14:09,610 --> 00:14:11,360 I said last time, with no market failures, 302 00:14:11,360 --> 00:14:13,280 government's just the bad guy. 303 00:14:13,280 --> 00:14:18,350 With no market failures, all government can do, 304 00:14:18,350 --> 00:14:19,960 it can help with the redistribution. 305 00:14:19,960 --> 00:14:21,290 But from an efficiency perspective, 306 00:14:21,290 --> 00:14:23,290 all the government can do is muck up the market. 307 00:14:23,290 --> 00:14:25,160 But once there's a market failure, 308 00:14:25,160 --> 00:14:28,700 there's a potential role for the government addressing it. 309 00:14:28,700 --> 00:14:31,370 So to see that, let's return to our monopoly example 310 00:14:31,370 --> 00:14:36,320 from last time in figure 12.2. 311 00:14:36,320 --> 00:14:39,840 Figure 12.2 is our monopoly example from last time. 312 00:14:39,840 --> 00:14:42,690 Remember, we had demand curve that 313 00:14:42,690 --> 00:14:47,170 was Q equals 24 minus P. We had a cost 314 00:14:47,170 --> 00:14:52,290 curve that delivered the marginal cost of MC equals 2Q. 315 00:14:52,290 --> 00:14:55,320 And that's graphed here. 316 00:14:55,320 --> 00:14:59,340 And we said last time that the monopoly outcome 317 00:14:59,340 --> 00:15:02,610 would be at E sub M. The monopolist would sell 318 00:15:02,610 --> 00:15:04,710 6 units at the price of 18, creating 319 00:15:04,710 --> 00:15:08,500 a deadweight loss of C plus E. 320 00:15:08,500 --> 00:15:13,780 Now, what if the government came along and simply mandated 321 00:15:13,780 --> 00:15:18,797 that the monopolist was not allowed to charge more than 16? 322 00:15:18,797 --> 00:15:21,130 The government says, look, I understand it's a monopoly. 323 00:15:21,130 --> 00:15:22,570 I'm not going to try to break up the monopoly. 324 00:15:22,570 --> 00:15:24,040 It's a natural monopoly, whatever. 325 00:15:24,040 --> 00:15:26,900 Simple rule-- price ceiling of 16. 326 00:15:26,900 --> 00:15:29,440 Now, when I mentioned pricing a couple of lectures ago, 327 00:15:29,440 --> 00:15:30,940 you should have learned to say, boo, 328 00:15:30,940 --> 00:15:33,940 price ceilings, bad, increase deadweight loss, terrible. 329 00:15:33,940 --> 00:15:36,790 But now, suddenly a price ceiling 330 00:15:36,790 --> 00:15:39,290 can actually get rid of deadweight loss. 331 00:15:39,290 --> 00:15:40,390 How's that possible? 332 00:15:40,390 --> 00:15:41,140 Let's take a look. 333 00:15:43,830 --> 00:15:48,510 In this case, the monopolist knew marginal revenue curve 334 00:15:48,510 --> 00:15:51,660 is a bit different. 335 00:15:51,660 --> 00:15:55,380 The new marginal revenue curve is the old marginal revenue 336 00:15:55,380 --> 00:16:00,700 curve, until you get to the point 337 00:16:00,700 --> 00:16:04,750 where the first dashed line intersects marginal revenue. 338 00:16:04,750 --> 00:16:07,180 It's the old marginal revenue curve, 339 00:16:07,180 --> 00:16:11,900 until you get where the marginal cost crosses marginal revenue. 340 00:16:11,900 --> 00:16:15,830 Then it jumps to the flat line at 16. 341 00:16:23,300 --> 00:16:25,880 Essentially, the new marginal revenue curve 342 00:16:25,880 --> 00:16:28,057 is downward sloping till the point 343 00:16:28,057 --> 00:16:29,890 where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. 344 00:16:29,890 --> 00:16:33,890 Then it jumps back up to the flat part 345 00:16:33,890 --> 00:16:37,130 that goes from 6 to 8. 346 00:16:37,130 --> 00:16:39,020 Now the exact shape doesn't matter. 347 00:16:39,020 --> 00:16:40,820 It's the intuition that matters. 348 00:16:40,820 --> 00:16:42,410 The point is the following. 349 00:16:42,410 --> 00:16:44,870 Think about the monopolist's decision. 350 00:16:44,870 --> 00:16:48,170 He decides, based on the logic of the last time, 351 00:16:48,170 --> 00:16:49,400 to sell six units. 352 00:16:49,400 --> 00:16:50,900 That's the point where the poisoning 353 00:16:50,900 --> 00:16:53,867 effect offsets the benefits of selling another unit. 354 00:16:53,867 --> 00:16:55,700 Now let's say the government comes and says, 355 00:16:55,700 --> 00:16:58,952 monopolists, you can't charge more than 16. 356 00:16:58,952 --> 00:17:01,760 Well, once a monopolist is forced to charge 16, 357 00:17:01,760 --> 00:17:06,530 now think about her decision to sell the seventh unit. 358 00:17:06,530 --> 00:17:08,849 Well, before she didn't want to sell the seventh unit, 359 00:17:08,849 --> 00:17:10,819 because selling the seventh unit meant she 360 00:17:10,819 --> 00:17:13,400 had to lower the price to 17. 361 00:17:13,400 --> 00:17:16,130 Well now she has to lower the price to 16 already, 362 00:17:16,130 --> 00:17:18,140 so why not sell the seventh unit? 363 00:17:18,140 --> 00:17:21,700 Indeed, why not sell the eighth unit? 364 00:17:21,700 --> 00:17:24,369 We've essentially gotten rid of the poisoning effect 365 00:17:24,369 --> 00:17:26,890 by pre-poisoning them, by already telling them, look, 366 00:17:26,890 --> 00:17:29,020 you can't charge more than 16. 367 00:17:29,020 --> 00:17:30,920 There's no way to charge more than that, 368 00:17:30,920 --> 00:17:34,960 so you might as well sell eight units. 369 00:17:34,960 --> 00:17:36,970 So by telling the monopolist they 370 00:17:36,970 --> 00:17:39,130 have to charge a competitive price, 371 00:17:39,130 --> 00:17:42,190 you will force them to sell the competitive quantity 372 00:17:42,190 --> 00:17:44,450 and you get rid of deadweight loss. 373 00:17:44,450 --> 00:17:47,080 That's our first example of how the government has 374 00:17:47,080 --> 00:17:48,773 improved things. 375 00:17:48,773 --> 00:17:50,940 The government has gotten rid of the deadweight loss 376 00:17:50,940 --> 00:17:52,830 by setting a price ceiling. 377 00:17:52,830 --> 00:17:55,560 Price ceiling, in a perfect market, is only bad, 378 00:17:55,560 --> 00:18:00,830 but a price ceiling here can actually improve things. 379 00:18:00,830 --> 00:18:03,560 So that actually sounds pretty good. 380 00:18:03,560 --> 00:18:04,677 So what's the problem? 381 00:18:04,677 --> 00:18:06,260 Why not, in reality, just say, hey, we 382 00:18:06,260 --> 00:18:07,718 can solve all our monopoly problems 383 00:18:07,718 --> 00:18:09,770 by just having the government regulate the price 384 00:18:09,770 --> 00:18:11,785 at the competitive level? 385 00:18:11,785 --> 00:18:13,910 What's the problem, in reality, with that solution? 386 00:18:13,910 --> 00:18:14,050 Yeah. 387 00:18:14,050 --> 00:18:15,364 AUDIENCE: How would the government 388 00:18:15,364 --> 00:18:16,420 know the competitive level? 389 00:18:16,420 --> 00:18:17,200 JONATHAN GRUBER: How the hell does the government 390 00:18:17,200 --> 00:18:18,117 the competitive level? 391 00:18:18,117 --> 00:18:19,610 It's great with this chart. 392 00:18:19,610 --> 00:18:21,225 But in reality, the government doesn't 393 00:18:21,225 --> 00:18:23,350 know where the competitive level is because there's 394 00:18:23,350 --> 00:18:24,225 two difficult points. 395 00:18:24,225 --> 00:18:25,933 What does the government need to collect? 396 00:18:25,933 --> 00:18:27,640 First of all, the government needs 397 00:18:27,640 --> 00:18:30,435 to know what the demand curve is. 398 00:18:30,435 --> 00:18:31,810 Well, it turns out demand curve's 399 00:18:31,810 --> 00:18:37,720 aren't written on our foreheads or out there on the dark web. 400 00:18:37,720 --> 00:18:40,360 Demand curves are something which you have to estimate. 401 00:18:40,360 --> 00:18:42,460 You have to gather information from people. 402 00:18:42,460 --> 00:18:45,070 And it turns out that it's pretty hard. 403 00:18:45,070 --> 00:18:47,680 Because if you want to gather information 404 00:18:47,680 --> 00:18:50,050 on what people are willing to pay for apples, 405 00:18:50,050 --> 00:18:52,383 you can just go to stores and look at the prices charged 406 00:18:52,383 --> 00:18:53,090 for apples. 407 00:18:53,090 --> 00:18:54,610 But if you want to gather information on the willingness 408 00:18:54,610 --> 00:18:56,770 to pay for getting water delivered to your house, 409 00:18:56,770 --> 00:18:59,500 there's no market to turn to. 410 00:18:59,500 --> 00:19:02,110 It turns out to be pretty hard to figure out 411 00:19:02,110 --> 00:19:05,740 how you value a lot of goods, which is natural monopolies. 412 00:19:05,740 --> 00:19:08,183 Now, you might say, well, why do you just ask 413 00:19:08,183 --> 00:19:09,475 people what it's worth to them? 414 00:19:09,475 --> 00:19:12,160 You just say to people, look, tell me you demand for water. 415 00:19:12,160 --> 00:19:14,368 It turns out that's really hard because people aren't 416 00:19:14,368 --> 00:19:17,080 very good at thinking about how to assign prices 417 00:19:17,080 --> 00:19:18,370 to things they don't shop for. 418 00:19:22,310 --> 00:19:24,050 If I say to you, what's an apple worth, 419 00:19:24,050 --> 00:19:24,920 the first thing in your head is, you 420 00:19:24,920 --> 00:19:26,390 think about being in a supermarket looking at apples 421 00:19:26,390 --> 00:19:27,480 and what they cost. 422 00:19:27,480 --> 00:19:29,147 You don't think about the inherent value 423 00:19:29,147 --> 00:19:32,240 to you of consuming an apple. 424 00:19:32,240 --> 00:19:34,525 But when you think about what water is worth, 425 00:19:34,525 --> 00:19:36,650 you have to think about sort of the inherent value. 426 00:19:36,650 --> 00:19:38,930 And so you have to rely on something 427 00:19:38,930 --> 00:19:44,570 that we call contingent valuation, which 428 00:19:44,570 --> 00:19:46,670 is the economist's fancy word for just asking 429 00:19:46,670 --> 00:19:47,962 people what it's worth to them. 430 00:19:50,635 --> 00:19:52,760 The problem is, people aren't very good about that. 431 00:19:52,760 --> 00:19:55,060 So for example, a classic case was the rise 432 00:19:55,060 --> 00:19:57,180 in environmental issues. 433 00:19:57,180 --> 00:19:59,270 How much is it worth to have clean air? 434 00:19:59,270 --> 00:20:02,580 How much is it worth to save the Grand Canyon? 435 00:20:02,580 --> 00:20:04,770 So it turns out people give sort of crazy answers 436 00:20:04,770 --> 00:20:08,935 that violate all the rules we set up in the first lecture 437 00:20:08,935 --> 00:20:09,810 by utility functions. 438 00:20:09,810 --> 00:20:12,215 Like for example, if you asked folks 439 00:20:12,215 --> 00:20:13,590 what it's worth to save the Grand 440 00:20:13,590 --> 00:20:16,740 Canyon as a single question, and then you ask them 441 00:20:16,740 --> 00:20:20,520 as the third question on the list, it's worth 1/5 as much 442 00:20:20,520 --> 00:20:23,150 to save the Grand Canyon was the third question on the list, 443 00:20:23,150 --> 00:20:24,472 which doesn't make any sense. 444 00:20:24,472 --> 00:20:26,430 It doesn't matter what the other questions are. 445 00:20:26,430 --> 00:20:28,770 If you ask people, how much they would 446 00:20:28,770 --> 00:20:32,600 pay to save seals and whales, in that order, 447 00:20:32,600 --> 00:20:40,410 they'd say saving seals is worth $142 and whales $195. 448 00:20:40,410 --> 00:20:42,140 So whales and seals are about the same. 449 00:20:42,140 --> 00:20:44,040 But when you reverse the order, whales 450 00:20:44,040 --> 00:20:46,260 are worth about twice what seals are worth, just 451 00:20:46,260 --> 00:20:47,950 by reversing the order. 452 00:20:47,950 --> 00:20:49,560 Well, more relevantly, if you ask 453 00:20:49,560 --> 00:20:51,990 people what it's worth to save a bird or 10 birds 454 00:20:51,990 --> 00:20:53,530 or 1,000 birds or a million birds, 455 00:20:53,530 --> 00:20:55,890 they give you pretty much the same answer, 456 00:20:55,890 --> 00:20:57,730 which doesn't make any sense. 457 00:20:57,730 --> 00:21:00,330 So basically, the problem is these contingent valuation 458 00:21:00,330 --> 00:21:03,060 methods don't really give sensible answers. 459 00:21:03,060 --> 00:21:05,328 And it's very hard to get sensible answers. 460 00:21:05,328 --> 00:21:06,870 In my other course, Public Economics, 461 00:21:06,870 --> 00:21:09,780 we talk about lots of interesting clever methods 462 00:21:09,780 --> 00:21:11,970 for trying to get people to reveal their preferences 463 00:21:11,970 --> 00:21:13,290 for these public goods. 464 00:21:13,290 --> 00:21:14,775 But it turns out to be hard. 465 00:21:14,775 --> 00:21:17,150 So that's one problem, is it's hard to measure the demand 466 00:21:17,150 --> 00:21:18,240 curve. 467 00:21:18,240 --> 00:21:21,870 The other problem is, it's hard to measure the supply curve. 468 00:21:21,870 --> 00:21:24,360 Because where does supply curve come from? 469 00:21:24,360 --> 00:21:27,000 It's sort of a firm's marginal cost function. 470 00:21:27,000 --> 00:21:31,170 You as the regulator do not know what their marginal cost 471 00:21:31,170 --> 00:21:32,490 function is. 472 00:21:32,490 --> 00:21:33,510 So how do you find out? 473 00:21:33,510 --> 00:21:34,420 You ask them. 474 00:21:34,420 --> 00:21:37,170 You say, hey, business I'm going to regulate, 475 00:21:37,170 --> 00:21:39,090 I'd like to know what your marginal cost is. 476 00:21:39,090 --> 00:21:41,310 And by the way, the lower you tell me 477 00:21:41,310 --> 00:21:44,032 it is, the lower price I'm going to let you charge. 478 00:21:44,032 --> 00:21:45,240 So what's your marginal cost? 479 00:21:45,240 --> 00:21:47,325 Oh, god, our marginal cost is horribly high. 480 00:21:47,325 --> 00:21:48,080 It terrible. 481 00:21:48,080 --> 00:21:50,078 You wouldn't believe it, can't complain 482 00:21:50,078 --> 00:21:51,870 enough about how high our marginal cost is. 483 00:21:51,870 --> 00:21:54,630 And basically, unless the regulator perfectly knows 484 00:21:54,630 --> 00:21:56,460 the production function and perfectly knows 485 00:21:56,460 --> 00:21:58,585 the input prices, none of which are perfectly known 486 00:21:58,585 --> 00:22:00,183 by anybody but the firm, they aren't 487 00:22:00,183 --> 00:22:02,100 going to know what the supply curve looks like 488 00:22:02,100 --> 00:22:03,910 and what the marginal cost looks like. 489 00:22:03,910 --> 00:22:05,481 Question. 490 00:22:05,481 --> 00:22:09,530 AUDIENCE: Couldn't they also, say, in a public company, 491 00:22:09,530 --> 00:22:12,320 basically inspect their factory and manufacturing [INAUDIBLE]?? 492 00:22:12,320 --> 00:22:13,500 JONATHAN GRUBER: You could absolutely do that 493 00:22:13,500 --> 00:22:15,150 and you can try to collect data. 494 00:22:15,150 --> 00:22:18,200 But ultimately, they could, that day that you show up 495 00:22:18,200 --> 00:22:21,140 with the inspector, have a really expensive-looking setup 496 00:22:21,140 --> 00:22:22,460 in their factory or whatever. 497 00:22:22,460 --> 00:22:26,120 It's basically very, very hard. 498 00:22:26,120 --> 00:22:31,292 So basically, the problem is that regulation-- and this 499 00:22:31,292 --> 00:22:32,750 will generally be a feature when we 500 00:22:32,750 --> 00:22:35,420 talk about the benefits of government intervention. 501 00:22:35,420 --> 00:22:39,557 We'll say, market failure makes it possible 502 00:22:39,557 --> 00:22:41,390 that government intervention can make things 503 00:22:41,390 --> 00:22:43,682 better, but not definite. 504 00:22:43,682 --> 00:22:45,140 So the way to think about the logic 505 00:22:45,140 --> 00:22:48,230 is, in a perfectly competitive market with no market failure, 506 00:22:48,230 --> 00:22:51,210 government intervention only makes things less efficient. 507 00:22:51,210 --> 00:22:52,850 We're leaving redistribution aside. 508 00:22:52,850 --> 00:22:54,650 It only makes things less efficient. 509 00:22:54,650 --> 00:22:56,720 When you move to markets with failure, 510 00:22:56,720 --> 00:22:59,510 you open up the possibility that government intervention 511 00:22:59,510 --> 00:23:02,850 can make things better, but not for sure that it will. 512 00:23:02,850 --> 00:23:04,700 You open up the possibility. 513 00:23:04,700 --> 00:23:06,710 It's a necessary but not a sufficient condition 514 00:23:06,710 --> 00:23:08,880 for saying the government improves efficiency. 515 00:23:08,880 --> 00:23:13,400 So for example, imagine that the government came in 516 00:23:13,400 --> 00:23:15,830 to this market and said, we think 517 00:23:15,830 --> 00:23:19,640 the competitive price is 10. 518 00:23:19,640 --> 00:23:21,460 We think the competitive price is 10. 519 00:23:21,460 --> 00:23:24,470 Well, if the government set the price equal to 10, 520 00:23:24,470 --> 00:23:28,810 we know that firms are going to produce 521 00:23:28,810 --> 00:23:31,533 where marginal revenue-- 522 00:23:31,533 --> 00:23:32,950 which is now just 10, because it's 523 00:23:32,950 --> 00:23:39,310 regulated-- equals marginal cost, so where 10 equals 2q. 524 00:23:39,310 --> 00:23:41,960 Little q and big Q are the same because of the monopolist. 525 00:23:41,960 --> 00:23:45,910 Where 10 equals 2q, or where q equals 5. 526 00:23:45,910 --> 00:23:47,590 So if the government comes in and says, 527 00:23:47,590 --> 00:23:49,360 we're fixing your price at 10, we 528 00:23:49,360 --> 00:23:51,976 know the firm produced five units. 529 00:23:51,976 --> 00:23:55,468 Well, with five units, the deadweight loss is even bigger. 530 00:23:55,468 --> 00:23:58,010 The key trick with deadweight loss triangles, deadweight loss 531 00:23:58,010 --> 00:24:00,350 is essentially proportional to how far you 532 00:24:00,350 --> 00:24:02,050 deviate from the optimal point. 533 00:24:02,050 --> 00:24:03,470 So the more you move to the left, 534 00:24:03,470 --> 00:24:05,600 the bigger the deadweight loss triangle is going to get. 535 00:24:05,600 --> 00:24:07,100 So deadweight loss with 5 units sold 536 00:24:07,100 --> 00:24:09,520 is bigger than deadweight loss with 6 units sold. 537 00:24:09,520 --> 00:24:12,590 So the government's actually made things worse. 538 00:24:12,590 --> 00:24:14,460 By coming and setting this price of 10, 539 00:24:14,460 --> 00:24:17,690 the government's made things worse. 540 00:24:17,690 --> 00:24:19,340 Indeed, the government could actually 541 00:24:19,340 --> 00:24:21,442 set the price so low you shut down. 542 00:24:21,442 --> 00:24:23,900 The government could set the price below the shutdown point 543 00:24:23,900 --> 00:24:26,970 and wipe the whole business off the map. 544 00:24:26,970 --> 00:24:28,790 So here we have the tradeoff. 545 00:24:28,790 --> 00:24:30,290 The government can potentially make 546 00:24:30,290 --> 00:24:32,473 the market more efficient through price regulation, 547 00:24:32,473 --> 00:24:33,515 but it won't necessarily. 548 00:24:33,515 --> 00:24:35,217 It depends on its level of information 549 00:24:35,217 --> 00:24:36,800 and how well it does setting the price 550 00:24:36,800 --> 00:24:38,930 relative to the competitive price. 551 00:24:41,960 --> 00:24:44,300 So basically, this is a very sort 552 00:24:44,300 --> 00:24:50,780 of interesting and difficult problem for the government. 553 00:24:50,780 --> 00:24:52,970 So one way is through regulation. 554 00:24:52,970 --> 00:24:55,250 Questions about that? 555 00:24:55,250 --> 00:24:58,340 The other way to try to address monopoly is by saying, 556 00:24:58,340 --> 00:25:02,930 is there some way to introduce competition? 557 00:25:02,930 --> 00:25:06,740 That is, even in what feels like a natural monopoly market, 558 00:25:06,740 --> 00:25:10,630 is there some way to choose competition? 559 00:25:10,630 --> 00:25:15,560 So for example, think about broadband delivery. 560 00:25:15,560 --> 00:25:16,670 Now we're still wired. 561 00:25:16,670 --> 00:25:17,660 In the future, it's all wireless. 562 00:25:17,660 --> 00:25:18,410 This is different. 563 00:25:18,410 --> 00:25:20,085 But it's still wired. 564 00:25:20,085 --> 00:25:21,710 The way it works is, broadband delivery 565 00:25:21,710 --> 00:25:24,350 has features of a natural monopoly, which 566 00:25:24,350 --> 00:25:29,400 is, someone has to lay the wires to your house to deliver it. 567 00:25:29,400 --> 00:25:31,680 At the same time, once those wires are laid, 568 00:25:31,680 --> 00:25:36,090 it's a 0 marginal cost to allow you to connect to the internet. 569 00:25:36,090 --> 00:25:40,970 So what governments do in other countries, but not the US-- 570 00:25:40,970 --> 00:25:42,920 in the US, we have competition. 571 00:25:42,920 --> 00:25:46,070 Everybody lays their own lines down. 572 00:25:46,070 --> 00:25:48,460 In Europe, they recognize that's inefficient. 573 00:25:48,460 --> 00:25:49,460 It's a natural monopoly. 574 00:25:49,460 --> 00:25:52,220 What they do is, they have one set of publicly laid lines, 575 00:25:52,220 --> 00:25:56,330 and you compete to deliver content over those lines. 576 00:25:56,330 --> 00:26:00,890 So there's competition where the monopoly is not natural, 577 00:26:00,890 --> 00:26:03,542 which is over the speed and the quality. 578 00:26:03,542 --> 00:26:05,000 It's the quality of the connection. 579 00:26:05,000 --> 00:26:07,700 But the lines themselves, since that's a giant fixed cost, 580 00:26:07,700 --> 00:26:10,035 they realize there can't be competition over that. 581 00:26:10,035 --> 00:26:11,660 So that's one way you could try to deal 582 00:26:11,660 --> 00:26:12,730 with a natural monopoly. 583 00:26:12,730 --> 00:26:13,670 In other words, the government could 584 00:26:13,670 --> 00:26:15,753 control the pipes underground delivering the water 585 00:26:15,753 --> 00:26:19,220 and have firms compete over delivering the water to you. 586 00:26:19,220 --> 00:26:20,820 So that's one way to deal with it. 587 00:26:20,820 --> 00:26:24,510 Another example is to think about the public sector 588 00:26:24,510 --> 00:26:28,580 and think about education, education delivery. 589 00:26:28,580 --> 00:26:36,110 Now, for those of you who grew up in the US, 590 00:26:36,110 --> 00:26:40,060 you are evidence of the success of the US educational system. 591 00:26:40,060 --> 00:26:42,750 But you are the exception, not the rule. 592 00:26:42,750 --> 00:26:45,000 The US educational system, by international standards, 593 00:26:45,000 --> 00:26:47,950 performs very badly. 594 00:26:47,950 --> 00:26:49,840 Probably out of the top 30 countries, 595 00:26:49,840 --> 00:26:52,480 we're like 15th in terms of things like math scores 596 00:26:52,480 --> 00:26:54,460 and other things like that. 597 00:26:54,460 --> 00:26:56,890 Yet, we spend more money per pupil 598 00:26:56,890 --> 00:27:01,120 than any other educational system 599 00:27:01,120 --> 00:27:03,910 in the world by a large amount. 600 00:27:03,910 --> 00:27:08,440 So if you look at figure 12-3, figure 12-3 shows, 601 00:27:08,440 --> 00:27:12,040 in the blue, primary school spending per pupil, 602 00:27:12,040 --> 00:27:14,320 and in the red, eighth grade math scores. 603 00:27:14,320 --> 00:27:17,030 And you can see the US spends way more than other people, 604 00:27:17,030 --> 00:27:18,405 but our scores aren't any better. 605 00:27:18,405 --> 00:27:19,905 Indeed, it doesn't look like there's 606 00:27:19,905 --> 00:27:21,820 a very strong relationship here at all 607 00:27:21,820 --> 00:27:26,650 between how much countries spend and what you get in return. 608 00:27:26,650 --> 00:27:28,510 But at least it's quite striking how low 609 00:27:28,510 --> 00:27:32,360 the US is given how high our spending is. 610 00:27:32,360 --> 00:27:35,120 Now, why is that? 611 00:27:35,120 --> 00:27:42,630 One reason is because we have given local schools a monopoly. 612 00:27:42,630 --> 00:27:45,183 We have said to local schools, you 613 00:27:45,183 --> 00:27:47,850 have a monopoly where you get to deliver the education to anyone 614 00:27:47,850 --> 00:27:49,892 who lives within a certain radius of your school. 615 00:27:52,820 --> 00:27:55,190 We've created that natural monopoly. 616 00:27:55,190 --> 00:27:57,300 And once we created that natural monopoly, 617 00:27:57,300 --> 00:28:02,672 we reduce pressures on firms to produce efficiently. 618 00:28:02,672 --> 00:28:04,880 We've essentially said to firms, you have a monopoly. 619 00:28:04,880 --> 00:28:08,173 There's no reason you have to produce efficiently. 620 00:28:08,173 --> 00:28:09,590 Because there's no entry and exit, 621 00:28:09,590 --> 00:28:12,790 which can put those pressures on you. 622 00:28:12,790 --> 00:28:15,480 So in some sense, that's a government-created monopoly. 623 00:28:15,480 --> 00:28:20,060 Your local public school is a government-created monopoly. 624 00:28:20,060 --> 00:28:21,775 So what can we do for that? 625 00:28:21,775 --> 00:28:22,400 What can we do? 626 00:28:22,400 --> 00:28:24,440 Well, we can actually introduce competition. 627 00:28:24,440 --> 00:28:28,070 So for example, we can have public school choice, 628 00:28:28,070 --> 00:28:31,170 which many cities now have, where, in fact, you 629 00:28:31,170 --> 00:28:35,500 don't have to go to the school in your neighborhood. 630 00:28:35,500 --> 00:28:38,110 You can try to go to any school in the district. 631 00:28:38,110 --> 00:28:39,657 You can essentially enter a lottery 632 00:28:39,657 --> 00:28:41,990 and try to move around to other schools in the district. 633 00:28:41,990 --> 00:28:43,510 And that introduces competition. 634 00:28:43,510 --> 00:28:44,927 Because then the schools that want 635 00:28:44,927 --> 00:28:47,770 kids will have to be better and have 636 00:28:47,770 --> 00:28:49,176 to produce more efficiently. 637 00:28:52,610 --> 00:28:56,517 And then a further mode of that is, 638 00:28:56,517 --> 00:28:57,725 you can have charter schools. 639 00:29:00,350 --> 00:29:06,270 Charter schools are publicly funded, but not city provided. 640 00:29:06,270 --> 00:29:09,860 They're in between public schools and private schools. 641 00:29:09,860 --> 00:29:12,560 Charter schools are separate schools, 642 00:29:12,560 --> 00:29:15,290 which get funding from the government. 643 00:29:15,290 --> 00:29:18,635 But they aren't under the local government's control. 644 00:29:18,635 --> 00:29:20,510 Regulatory control, but they aren't delivered 645 00:29:20,510 --> 00:29:22,550 by the city as education. 646 00:29:22,550 --> 00:29:26,570 And that provides more public school choice for individuals. 647 00:29:26,570 --> 00:29:29,810 And there's a lot of evidence, much of it by my colleagues 648 00:29:29,810 --> 00:29:32,000 here at MIT, which shows that there's 649 00:29:32,000 --> 00:29:34,250 been enormous benefits to these movements, 650 00:29:34,250 --> 00:29:36,835 that public school choice and charter schools 651 00:29:36,835 --> 00:29:38,460 have delivered-- now I know some of you 652 00:29:38,460 --> 00:29:40,250 might have seen the John Oliver segment a couple of years 653 00:29:40,250 --> 00:29:41,875 ago where he ragged on charter schools. 654 00:29:41,875 --> 00:29:44,400 I mean, I love him in general, but he was wrong on that one. 655 00:29:44,400 --> 00:29:45,925 There's a couple of bad actors. 656 00:29:45,925 --> 00:29:47,300 But by and large, charter schools 657 00:29:47,300 --> 00:29:49,550 have been an enormous benefit to the education system 658 00:29:49,550 --> 00:29:54,080 by introducing competition and allowing students 659 00:29:54,080 --> 00:29:59,070 an option to improve their educational outcomes. 660 00:29:59,070 --> 00:30:01,970 Now, the furthest out option, and something 661 00:30:01,970 --> 00:30:04,785 you'll hear a lot of discussion of, is vouchers. 662 00:30:07,956 --> 00:30:10,890 The most radical option is what we call public school 663 00:30:10,890 --> 00:30:13,605 vouchers, or just vouchers. 664 00:30:13,605 --> 00:30:14,730 Here's how this would work. 665 00:30:14,730 --> 00:30:16,897 This is a very popular idea on the conservative side 666 00:30:16,897 --> 00:30:17,940 of the spectrum. 667 00:30:17,940 --> 00:30:19,150 Here's how this would work. 668 00:30:19,150 --> 00:30:21,030 So I live in Lexington. 669 00:30:21,030 --> 00:30:23,640 What that means is, if I send my kid to a Lexington 670 00:30:23,640 --> 00:30:27,440 public school, it's free. 671 00:30:27,440 --> 00:30:29,360 But the minute I pull my kid out and send him 672 00:30:29,360 --> 00:30:33,000 to a private school, it costs me the entire amount. 673 00:30:33,000 --> 00:30:35,250 So imagine a Lexington public school education's worth 674 00:30:35,250 --> 00:30:38,610 $10,000. 675 00:30:38,610 --> 00:30:42,660 I'm essentially getting $10,000, conditional on sending 676 00:30:42,660 --> 00:30:44,100 my kids to a Lexington school. 677 00:30:44,100 --> 00:30:45,892 The minute I choose to send them elsewhere, 678 00:30:45,892 --> 00:30:49,420 I literally give up that $10,000. 679 00:30:49,420 --> 00:30:51,490 A voucher system would say, the way it would work 680 00:30:51,490 --> 00:30:53,770 is, everyone in town would get a check 681 00:30:53,770 --> 00:30:57,040 or would get a voucher for $10,000 682 00:30:57,040 --> 00:30:59,218 to be used at any school they want. 683 00:30:59,218 --> 00:31:01,510 So if you want to go in Lexington, you just hand it in. 684 00:31:01,510 --> 00:31:03,190 Life's never changed. 685 00:31:03,190 --> 00:31:05,040 But now if you want to go to private school, 686 00:31:05,040 --> 00:31:07,460 we're allowing you to take your money elsewhere. 687 00:31:07,460 --> 00:31:09,110 That puts competitive pressure not just 688 00:31:09,110 --> 00:31:12,488 on schools within the district but on the whole district. 689 00:31:12,488 --> 00:31:14,280 The whole district now says, wait a second, 690 00:31:14,280 --> 00:31:15,760 if we don't do a good job, people 691 00:31:15,760 --> 00:31:17,906 are going to leave and take their money elsewhere. 692 00:31:17,906 --> 00:31:21,630 So the idea is to actually set up broader competition 693 00:31:21,630 --> 00:31:26,550 to put pressure on districts to improve their performance. 694 00:31:26,550 --> 00:31:28,600 So this has been a longtime attractive option 695 00:31:28,600 --> 00:31:30,630 to many economists. 696 00:31:30,630 --> 00:31:33,740 And I've spent a whole long time talking about the pros and cons 697 00:31:33,740 --> 00:31:35,180 of this in my other class. 698 00:31:35,180 --> 00:31:38,330 But briefly speaking, the pros are all the reasons 699 00:31:38,330 --> 00:31:40,420 we like competition in markets. 700 00:31:40,420 --> 00:31:42,920 It'll cause more production efficiency 701 00:31:42,920 --> 00:31:45,140 because schools would have to compete. 702 00:31:45,140 --> 00:31:47,150 The cons are numerous, though. 703 00:31:47,150 --> 00:31:51,357 One con is, you then have to have the public sector that 704 00:31:51,357 --> 00:31:53,690 has a vested interest in making sure private schools are 705 00:31:53,690 --> 00:31:57,000 delivering a public quality education. 706 00:31:57,000 --> 00:32:02,000 So basically, you could set up a private school that is just 707 00:32:02,000 --> 00:32:03,980 a football training academy. 708 00:32:03,980 --> 00:32:06,440 And suddenly, people could take their voucher and go there, 709 00:32:06,440 --> 00:32:08,160 and suddenly they wouldn't get education. 710 00:32:08,160 --> 00:32:09,950 That's one con. 711 00:32:09,950 --> 00:32:14,820 Another con of these systems is that they're expensive. 712 00:32:14,820 --> 00:32:15,667 So take me. 713 00:32:15,667 --> 00:32:16,500 I live in Lexington. 714 00:32:16,500 --> 00:32:17,780 I'm a pretty rich guy. 715 00:32:17,780 --> 00:32:20,870 I sent my kids to private school. 716 00:32:20,870 --> 00:32:22,130 I sent them and I paid. 717 00:32:22,130 --> 00:32:24,140 Now, imagine Lexington had a voucher system 718 00:32:24,140 --> 00:32:27,050 and they give me a check for $10,000. 719 00:32:27,050 --> 00:32:30,415 Why should Lexington give a relatively rich guy $10,000? 720 00:32:30,415 --> 00:32:31,290 That's sort of silly. 721 00:32:31,290 --> 00:32:33,290 I was already sending my kids to private school. 722 00:32:33,290 --> 00:32:35,600 So who would be the big winner from a system like this? 723 00:32:35,600 --> 00:32:37,100 Well, some winners would be kids who 724 00:32:37,100 --> 00:32:38,790 then get a better education. 725 00:32:38,790 --> 00:32:40,280 But a lot of winners would be rich people who already sent 726 00:32:40,280 --> 00:32:41,060 their kids to private school. 727 00:32:41,060 --> 00:32:42,500 We'd just be handing them checks. 728 00:32:42,500 --> 00:32:44,090 That's not a great outcome. 729 00:32:44,090 --> 00:32:47,810 So there are definitely tradeoffs 730 00:32:47,810 --> 00:32:49,470 inherent in a system like this. 731 00:32:49,470 --> 00:32:50,762 I know there's a few questions. 732 00:32:50,762 --> 00:32:52,887 Let's do a couple of questions, then we'll move on. 733 00:32:52,887 --> 00:32:53,880 Yeah, in the back. 734 00:32:53,880 --> 00:32:55,880 AUDIENCE: So say you have these vouchers, 735 00:32:55,880 --> 00:32:58,760 and instead of going to the public school, 736 00:32:58,760 --> 00:33:01,880 students are leaving to the private school, and then 737 00:33:01,880 --> 00:33:04,370 the fixed cost of having the infrastructure 738 00:33:04,370 --> 00:33:08,220 of a public school, that's then spread out over less students. 739 00:33:08,220 --> 00:33:12,440 So how do you account for, the price of teaching one student 740 00:33:12,440 --> 00:33:15,590 might go up if there are these students that are leaving? 741 00:33:15,590 --> 00:33:17,570 JONATHAN GRUBER: That is an awesome question. 742 00:33:17,570 --> 00:33:19,370 There's two elements to that. 743 00:33:19,370 --> 00:33:22,890 Question one is, there is an actual natural monopoly feature 744 00:33:22,890 --> 00:33:24,590 to local public education. 745 00:33:24,590 --> 00:33:27,190 So remember, competition doesn't make sense when 746 00:33:27,190 --> 00:33:28,575 it's a true natural monopoly. 747 00:33:28,575 --> 00:33:30,200 There is some natural monopoly element. 748 00:33:30,200 --> 00:33:33,290 So as you shrink the number, you suddenly 749 00:33:33,290 --> 00:33:34,850 are raising the average cost. 750 00:33:34,850 --> 00:33:36,350 And that is a potential problem. 751 00:33:36,350 --> 00:33:37,517 There's an efficiency issue. 752 00:33:37,517 --> 00:33:39,230 There's also an equity issue, which 753 00:33:39,230 --> 00:33:41,410 is, who uses the vouchers and leaves? 754 00:33:41,410 --> 00:33:43,815 The people with motivated parents who are with it. 755 00:33:43,815 --> 00:33:44,690 Who gets left behind? 756 00:33:44,690 --> 00:33:46,730 People's parents who don't give a shit about him. 757 00:33:46,730 --> 00:33:48,522 There's an equity issue, too, of, suddenly, 758 00:33:48,522 --> 00:33:50,993 you're pulling all the smart kids, all the motivated kids 759 00:33:50,993 --> 00:33:52,910 out of the public schools and leaving the kids 760 00:33:52,910 --> 00:33:55,260 behind who aren't motivated or whose parents aren't motivated. 761 00:33:55,260 --> 00:33:56,420 There's an equity issue there, too, 762 00:33:56,420 --> 00:33:57,545 so that's another tradeoff. 763 00:33:57,545 --> 00:33:58,396 Yeah. 764 00:33:58,396 --> 00:33:59,890 AUDIENCE: You got a good education. 765 00:33:59,890 --> 00:34:02,500 JONATHAN GRUBER: How do you tell if people get a good education? 766 00:34:02,500 --> 00:34:03,440 Well, that's [INAUDIBLE]. 767 00:34:03,440 --> 00:34:05,140 AUDIENCE: Well, if you're going to get a good education. 768 00:34:05,140 --> 00:34:07,220 JONATHAN GRUBER: Well, that's another problem. 769 00:34:07,220 --> 00:34:10,420 Which is, competition, one of our fundamental assumptions 770 00:34:10,420 --> 00:34:13,909 of perfect competition was perfect information. 771 00:34:13,909 --> 00:34:16,130 That's fine when you're looking at apples or maybe 772 00:34:16,130 --> 00:34:17,870 even computers. 773 00:34:17,870 --> 00:34:19,760 It's not so easy looking at schools. 774 00:34:19,760 --> 00:34:21,527 Now, schools publish test scores. 775 00:34:21,527 --> 00:34:24,110 You can look at the test scores of kids who go to that school. 776 00:34:24,110 --> 00:34:25,818 But once again, that's not that reliable, 777 00:34:25,818 --> 00:34:27,735 because if smart kids are going to the school, 778 00:34:27,735 --> 00:34:30,170 they'll have high test scores, even if teachers suck. 779 00:34:30,170 --> 00:34:32,750 For example, Harvard-- sorry, I couldn't resist. 780 00:34:32,750 --> 00:34:34,880 [LAUGHTER] 781 00:34:34,880 --> 00:34:42,090 So basically, you can't really tell that. 782 00:34:42,090 --> 00:34:45,469 In other words, there's a number of failures 783 00:34:45,469 --> 00:34:48,739 of the private education market, that 784 00:34:48,739 --> 00:34:51,568 are a problem with this kind of voucher solution. 785 00:34:51,568 --> 00:34:52,860 But it doesn't mean it's wrong. 786 00:34:52,860 --> 00:34:54,810 It means it's interesting. 787 00:34:54,810 --> 00:34:55,699 There's a tradeoff. 788 00:34:55,699 --> 00:34:57,653 On the one hand, we'd introduce competition, 789 00:34:57,653 --> 00:34:59,820 which would maybe increase efficiency in the market. 790 00:34:59,820 --> 00:35:01,420 On the other hand, there's a lot of market failures 791 00:35:01,420 --> 00:35:03,620 which might get in the way of this functioning properly. 792 00:35:03,620 --> 00:35:05,670 Fascinating topic, and if you want to learn more, 793 00:35:05,670 --> 00:35:06,920 I urge you take 1441. 794 00:35:06,920 --> 00:35:09,740 We spend a whole lecture talking about it. 795 00:35:09,740 --> 00:35:13,790 So that was the second topic I want to talk about. 796 00:35:13,790 --> 00:35:16,310 Once again, we've started down the road 797 00:35:16,310 --> 00:35:22,380 of questioning the wisdom of the market, so the road of market 798 00:35:22,380 --> 00:35:24,263 failures. 799 00:35:24,263 --> 00:35:25,680 The first market fail is monopoly. 800 00:35:25,680 --> 00:35:28,260 We've talked about the pros and cons of trying 801 00:35:28,260 --> 00:35:30,650 to deal with monopoly. 802 00:35:30,650 --> 00:35:33,110 But I want to talk about one other topic 803 00:35:33,110 --> 00:35:34,820 before we leave monopolies, which 804 00:35:34,820 --> 00:35:39,320 is this topic of what we call contestable markets, which 805 00:35:39,320 --> 00:35:42,440 is sort of an informal term. 806 00:35:42,440 --> 00:35:43,988 But I really like it as an intuition, 807 00:35:43,988 --> 00:35:45,530 so I'd like to spend some time on it. 808 00:35:48,620 --> 00:35:53,440 Contestable markets are monopoly markets without market power 809 00:35:53,440 --> 00:35:55,150 or without much market power. 810 00:35:55,150 --> 00:35:56,950 That is, we talked about monopolists 811 00:35:56,950 --> 00:35:59,020 as having lots of market power. 812 00:35:59,020 --> 00:36:03,080 Remember, we said the markup was essentially proportional. 813 00:36:03,080 --> 00:36:05,830 We said that monopolists had a markup, price 814 00:36:05,830 --> 00:36:09,100 minus marginal cost over price, which is equal to minus 1 815 00:36:09,100 --> 00:36:12,320 over the elasticity of demand. 816 00:36:12,320 --> 00:36:14,000 That was their markup. 817 00:36:14,000 --> 00:36:17,818 And so you know some markets, different monopoly markets 818 00:36:17,818 --> 00:36:19,610 will have different levels of market power. 819 00:36:19,610 --> 00:36:21,902 You can be a monopolist, but not have much market power 820 00:36:21,902 --> 00:36:24,130 if consumers are very elastic. 821 00:36:24,130 --> 00:36:27,940 But there's another reason why monopolists face pressure 822 00:36:27,940 --> 00:36:30,290 besides the elasticity of demand, 823 00:36:30,290 --> 00:36:34,008 which is, in some sense, the size of the barrier to entry. 824 00:36:34,008 --> 00:36:36,425 So one reason monopolists are constrained in their pricing 825 00:36:36,425 --> 00:36:38,750 is because demand's elastic. 826 00:36:38,750 --> 00:36:41,180 Another reason is because the barriers to entry 827 00:36:41,180 --> 00:36:44,080 might not be that large. 828 00:36:44,080 --> 00:36:45,670 So you could think of it, roughly 829 00:36:45,670 --> 00:36:49,180 speaking, for a given elasticity of demand, 830 00:36:49,180 --> 00:36:52,733 the larger the barrier to entry, the more market power you have. 831 00:36:52,733 --> 00:36:54,400 Because the larger the barrier to entry, 832 00:36:54,400 --> 00:36:56,650 the more you can be sure no other firm's going to come in. 833 00:36:56,650 --> 00:36:58,330 Or in other words, the amount to which 834 00:36:58,330 --> 00:37:02,530 you can charge above marginal cost for a given elasticity 835 00:37:02,530 --> 00:37:07,500 is proportional to how severe the barriers to entry are. 836 00:37:07,500 --> 00:37:10,950 If there's no way a second firm can get in, then essentially, 837 00:37:10,950 --> 00:37:13,730 you get to just obey this formula. 838 00:37:13,730 --> 00:37:16,073 But if a second firm can get in easily, 839 00:37:16,073 --> 00:37:18,490 then you might not even be able to have this big a markup. 840 00:37:18,490 --> 00:37:19,948 Because if you try, someone's going 841 00:37:19,948 --> 00:37:22,600 to come in and steal your profits. 842 00:37:22,600 --> 00:37:26,840 So in other words, there's essentially an important issue, 843 00:37:26,840 --> 00:37:28,540 which is that the market monopolists can 844 00:37:28,540 --> 00:37:31,232 get as a function both of elastic demand and the size 845 00:37:31,232 --> 00:37:33,270 of their barriers to entry. 846 00:37:33,270 --> 00:37:36,170 This is an important issue that came up 847 00:37:36,170 --> 00:37:41,120 in the area of airline deregulation, which 848 00:37:41,120 --> 00:37:43,280 is what I want to talk about for a few minutes. 849 00:37:43,280 --> 00:37:45,920 It's an important application of the kind of stuff 850 00:37:45,920 --> 00:37:47,170 we've been talking about. 851 00:37:47,170 --> 00:37:53,220 Now, how many of you have seen Mad Men. 852 00:37:53,220 --> 00:37:53,875 Jeez, really? 853 00:37:53,875 --> 00:37:55,250 Wow, OK, it's a pretty good show. 854 00:37:55,250 --> 00:37:56,520 I mean, it's not outstanding. 855 00:37:56,520 --> 00:37:58,230 How many have seen Breaking Bad? 856 00:37:58,230 --> 00:37:59,007 OK, good. 857 00:37:59,007 --> 00:38:00,090 That, you have to all see. 858 00:38:00,090 --> 00:38:02,042 Mad Men's pretty good. 859 00:38:02,042 --> 00:38:03,750 But basically, what's nice about Mad Men, 860 00:38:03,750 --> 00:38:06,880 it shows what flying was like when I was a kid. 861 00:38:06,880 --> 00:38:11,220 When I was a kid, when you flew, it was like luxurious. 862 00:38:11,220 --> 00:38:13,590 You went on, there was plenty of leg room. 863 00:38:13,590 --> 00:38:16,440 You had free meals, free movies, free drinks. 864 00:38:21,480 --> 00:38:23,970 And the reason was because-- 865 00:38:23,970 --> 00:38:25,590 I sort of skipped ahead in the story. 866 00:38:25,590 --> 00:38:28,530 When I was a kid, airlines were regulated. 867 00:38:28,530 --> 00:38:33,330 What that meant was that, essentially, 868 00:38:33,330 --> 00:38:36,870 the government viewed airlines as a natural monopoly. 869 00:38:36,870 --> 00:38:39,790 They said, look, planes are very expensive. 870 00:38:39,790 --> 00:38:42,722 There's a big fixed cost, so it's a natural monopoly. 871 00:38:42,722 --> 00:38:44,680 We don't think competition will work well here, 872 00:38:44,680 --> 00:38:46,962 so we're going to have regulation of airlines. 873 00:38:46,962 --> 00:38:48,420 What that meant was, the government 874 00:38:48,420 --> 00:38:51,300 set the price of every flight and regulated 875 00:38:51,300 --> 00:38:53,040 where planes could go. 876 00:38:53,040 --> 00:38:54,720 So airlines every year would submit 877 00:38:54,720 --> 00:38:57,390 a set of routes they wanted to fly and a set of prices. 878 00:38:57,390 --> 00:38:59,970 And the government would approve or turn them down. 879 00:38:59,970 --> 00:39:02,745 It was a regulated market. 880 00:39:02,745 --> 00:39:05,120 And it was generally viewed that the government basically 881 00:39:05,120 --> 00:39:07,580 sort of screwed this up and set the rates too high. 882 00:39:07,580 --> 00:39:08,600 That was sort of the general view, 883 00:39:08,600 --> 00:39:10,825 that, basically, government, because, essentially, they 884 00:39:10,825 --> 00:39:12,575 didn't really understand the supply curve, 885 00:39:12,575 --> 00:39:14,583 they were being fooled by the airlines 886 00:39:14,583 --> 00:39:17,000 to think costs were higher than they were and were setting 887 00:39:17,000 --> 00:39:19,700 prices too high. 888 00:39:19,700 --> 00:39:24,380 But economists said, look, this is not a natural monopoly. 889 00:39:24,380 --> 00:39:26,900 Because in fact, it's not actually 890 00:39:26,900 --> 00:39:32,120 that cheap to get a used plane and enter this business. 891 00:39:32,120 --> 00:39:35,240 Because these companies turn over their planes all the time. 892 00:39:35,240 --> 00:39:37,612 And yes, buying a new plane's expensive. 893 00:39:37,612 --> 00:39:39,320 But getting a well-functioning used plane 894 00:39:39,320 --> 00:39:40,640 isn't that expensive. 895 00:39:40,640 --> 00:39:43,730 And you could easily create competitors in this business. 896 00:39:43,730 --> 00:39:47,780 They said it was what we called a contestable market, a market 897 00:39:47,780 --> 00:39:51,830 with very low barriers to entry, that, in fact, 898 00:39:51,830 --> 00:39:54,800 if you allowed competition, you would have a lot of entry 899 00:39:54,800 --> 00:39:55,907 into this market. 900 00:39:55,907 --> 00:39:58,490 And it would function fine, that it wasn't a natural monopoly, 901 00:39:58,490 --> 00:40:01,535 it was a contestable market. 902 00:40:01,535 --> 00:40:03,910 And they argued, in fact, that if you lacked competition, 903 00:40:03,910 --> 00:40:08,580 price would fall very close to marginal cost. 904 00:40:08,580 --> 00:40:11,270 Price could fall very close to marginal cost. 905 00:40:11,270 --> 00:40:13,980 So in fact, economists carried the day. 906 00:40:13,980 --> 00:40:17,540 In the 1970s, we deregulated the airline industry. 907 00:40:17,540 --> 00:40:20,570 The government stopped setting prices and regulating routes. 908 00:40:20,570 --> 00:40:21,950 What happened? 909 00:40:21,950 --> 00:40:24,880 OK, three things happened. 910 00:40:24,880 --> 00:40:28,150 The first thing is, price fell enormously. 911 00:40:28,150 --> 00:40:31,940 The cost of flying fell by about 1/3. 912 00:40:31,940 --> 00:40:36,830 The best example was the airline I took home from MIT in 1984 913 00:40:36,830 --> 00:40:38,760 called People Express. 914 00:40:38,760 --> 00:40:40,260 People Express Airlines introduced-- 915 00:40:40,260 --> 00:40:43,100 this was sort of shortly after deregulation. 916 00:40:43,100 --> 00:40:49,100 I could fly from Boston to Newark for $29. 917 00:40:49,100 --> 00:40:50,728 Now, how did that work? 918 00:40:50,728 --> 00:40:51,270 It was crazy. 919 00:40:51,270 --> 00:40:52,790 You showed up at the airport. 920 00:40:52,790 --> 00:40:53,873 There was no reservations. 921 00:40:53,873 --> 00:40:55,160 You just waited on line. 922 00:40:55,160 --> 00:40:56,580 They let people on until the plane was full. 923 00:40:56,580 --> 00:40:58,040 Then you waited for the next one. 924 00:40:58,040 --> 00:41:00,062 You paid on the plane with a credit card. 925 00:41:00,062 --> 00:41:01,520 I still to this day don't know what 926 00:41:01,520 --> 00:41:02,340 happened if you didn't pay. 927 00:41:02,340 --> 00:41:03,370 Did they throw you out the window? 928 00:41:03,370 --> 00:41:04,170 I don't know. 929 00:41:04,170 --> 00:41:05,870 But you paid on the plane. 930 00:41:05,870 --> 00:41:07,550 And it was incredibly competitive. 931 00:41:07,550 --> 00:41:08,633 And this is what happened. 932 00:41:08,633 --> 00:41:11,480 Flying got incredibly cheap. 933 00:41:11,480 --> 00:41:17,910 The second thing that happened is you had many more routes. 934 00:41:17,910 --> 00:41:19,630 It turned out that the government 935 00:41:19,630 --> 00:41:21,580 thought that flying from point A to point B 936 00:41:21,580 --> 00:41:23,532 wasn't profitable often when it was. 937 00:41:23,532 --> 00:41:25,990 So the government wouldn't let airlines flight from point A 938 00:41:25,990 --> 00:41:27,730 to point B, when, if fact, airlines 939 00:41:27,730 --> 00:41:29,850 could make plenty of money doing that flight. 940 00:41:29,850 --> 00:41:34,570 So you had cheaper flights and more routes. 941 00:41:34,570 --> 00:41:37,840 The third thing is, flying sucks. 942 00:41:41,710 --> 00:41:44,050 When I was a kid, flying was awesome-- 943 00:41:44,050 --> 00:41:46,600 meals, booze, big seats. 944 00:41:46,600 --> 00:41:51,820 Now it's terrible-- no meals, no booze, tiny seats. 945 00:41:51,820 --> 00:41:53,447 Why? 946 00:41:53,447 --> 00:41:54,280 Why did this happen? 947 00:41:56,352 --> 00:41:58,310 Flights got cheaper and there are more of them, 948 00:41:58,310 --> 00:42:01,980 but why were they suddenly crappier? 949 00:42:01,980 --> 00:42:02,660 Yeah. 950 00:42:02,660 --> 00:42:04,160 AUDIENCE: There was more competition 951 00:42:04,160 --> 00:42:06,880 so they were trying to bring down the marginal cost so bring 952 00:42:06,880 --> 00:42:07,990 prices lower. 953 00:42:07,990 --> 00:42:10,032 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right, that's one way to put it. 954 00:42:10,032 --> 00:42:13,600 But the point is, what this example points out 955 00:42:13,600 --> 00:42:15,350 is that there's always competition. 956 00:42:15,350 --> 00:42:16,090 Yeah, what were you going to say? 957 00:42:16,090 --> 00:42:17,350 AUDIENCE: I was going to say price discrimination. 958 00:42:17,350 --> 00:42:19,720 They could discriminate based on what people [INAUDIBLE] 959 00:42:19,720 --> 00:42:20,290 JONATHAN GRUBER: It actually wasn't. 960 00:42:20,290 --> 00:42:21,070 They still price discriminate. 961 00:42:21,070 --> 00:42:22,360 It wasn't quite that. 962 00:42:22,360 --> 00:42:23,430 But yeah. 963 00:42:23,430 --> 00:42:26,670 AUDIENCE: People were willing to fly [INAUDIBLE] 964 00:42:26,670 --> 00:42:28,420 JONATHAN GRUBER: They were willing to fly. 965 00:42:28,420 --> 00:42:29,800 But what were they doing before? 966 00:42:29,800 --> 00:42:30,740 Yeah. 967 00:42:30,740 --> 00:42:33,520 AUDIENCE: If you couldn't compete on price, 968 00:42:33,520 --> 00:42:35,592 you could compete on luxuriousness. 969 00:42:35,592 --> 00:42:36,550 JONATHAN GRUBER: Right. 970 00:42:36,550 --> 00:42:38,020 So there were multiple airlines before. 971 00:42:38,020 --> 00:42:40,020 The government said we'll only compete on price. 972 00:42:40,020 --> 00:42:43,130 But they said, great, we'll compete on other stuff. 973 00:42:43,130 --> 00:42:45,830 Remember, economic actors want to be economic actors. 974 00:42:45,830 --> 00:42:47,937 They want to use economic tools. 975 00:42:47,937 --> 00:42:49,520 So if the government says to airlines, 976 00:42:49,520 --> 00:42:50,900 we're not going to let you charge a higher price, 977 00:42:50,900 --> 00:42:52,275 they're like great, we'll compete 978 00:42:52,275 --> 00:42:56,420 by having better food, better drinks, bigger seats. 979 00:42:56,420 --> 00:42:57,830 Once the government said, now you 980 00:42:57,830 --> 00:43:00,320 have a new mode of competing, they 981 00:43:00,320 --> 00:43:02,485 realized people weren't willing to pay 982 00:43:02,485 --> 00:43:04,610 for better food and better drinks and bigger seats. 983 00:43:04,610 --> 00:43:06,483 They'd rather fly cheaper. 984 00:43:06,483 --> 00:43:08,150 So they switched the mode of competition 985 00:43:08,150 --> 00:43:12,050 from quality competition to price competition. 986 00:43:12,050 --> 00:43:14,450 They used to use quality competition. 987 00:43:14,450 --> 00:43:17,000 Now they use price competition. 988 00:43:17,000 --> 00:43:20,150 This means that all of us who complain that flying sucks 989 00:43:20,150 --> 00:43:22,140 should just shut up. 990 00:43:22,140 --> 00:43:24,060 Because if we really cared that much, 991 00:43:24,060 --> 00:43:27,370 then there'd be a good airline that charged more and gave you 992 00:43:27,370 --> 00:43:28,083 better stuff. 993 00:43:28,083 --> 00:43:28,750 But there's not. 994 00:43:28,750 --> 00:43:30,350 I mean, JetBlue's a little better. 995 00:43:30,350 --> 00:43:33,490 But by and large, there's not airlines 996 00:43:33,490 --> 00:43:35,820 that charge more and give you better stuff. 997 00:43:35,820 --> 00:43:37,570 And that's because, at the end of the day, 998 00:43:37,570 --> 00:43:40,090 we would rather fly cheaper than have this extra stuff. 999 00:43:40,090 --> 00:43:42,680 It wasn't worth the money that we were paying for it. 1000 00:43:45,490 --> 00:43:49,180 Which really says that regulation was failing here. 1001 00:43:49,180 --> 00:43:51,430 Regulation was forcing airlines to compete 1002 00:43:51,430 --> 00:43:53,120 in an inefficient way. 1003 00:43:53,120 --> 00:43:56,320 They're competing by giving us nice meals when we would rather 1004 00:43:56,320 --> 00:43:57,970 have the money. 1005 00:43:57,970 --> 00:44:02,350 So it was an example that regulation failed. 1006 00:44:02,350 --> 00:44:04,610 So that's all really good news. 1007 00:44:04,610 --> 00:44:08,050 But there's one piece of bad news, which is that, economists 1008 00:44:08,050 --> 00:44:09,670 aren't all-knowing. 1009 00:44:09,670 --> 00:44:13,690 And the economists, there's a fourth outcome we missed, 1010 00:44:13,690 --> 00:44:16,090 which was the rise of the hub and spoke system. 1011 00:44:18,850 --> 00:44:22,740 Which is that what we missed is that airplanes 1012 00:44:22,740 --> 00:44:27,460 aren't a natural monopoly, but airports are. 1013 00:44:27,460 --> 00:44:30,720 And what airlines started doing is essentially 1014 00:44:30,720 --> 00:44:36,190 taking over airport slots, and then saying, 1015 00:44:36,190 --> 00:44:37,760 we are going to have all the flights. 1016 00:44:37,760 --> 00:44:39,593 So for example, my wife is from Minneapolis. 1017 00:44:39,593 --> 00:44:42,440 We used to go to Minneapolis, the only option was Northwest. 1018 00:44:42,440 --> 00:44:45,200 Northwest owned all the slots in the Minneapolis airport. 1019 00:44:45,200 --> 00:44:47,450 And they'd say, if you ever fly anywhere on Northwest, 1020 00:44:47,450 --> 00:44:51,025 we're going to route you from Minneapolis to wherever you go. 1021 00:44:51,025 --> 00:44:52,650 It was called the hub and spoke system. 1022 00:44:52,650 --> 00:44:54,650 You always went to a central point and went out. 1023 00:44:54,650 --> 00:44:56,220 So US Air had Pittsburgh. 1024 00:44:56,220 --> 00:44:58,960 Northwest had Minneapolis. 1025 00:44:58,960 --> 00:45:00,290 American had Dallas, et cetera. 1026 00:45:00,290 --> 00:45:02,040 They had these hubs that you'd go through. 1027 00:45:02,040 --> 00:45:03,720 What that meant was, they essentially 1028 00:45:03,720 --> 00:45:06,480 got a monopoly on the route into the hubs, 1029 00:45:06,480 --> 00:45:10,457 because they had monopoly on the slots in the airport. 1030 00:45:10,457 --> 00:45:12,290 Now you might say, well, that's easy to fix. 1031 00:45:12,290 --> 00:45:14,030 Don't give monopoly slots in the airport. 1032 00:45:14,030 --> 00:45:15,838 But that's harder to fix than you think. 1033 00:45:15,838 --> 00:45:17,630 Because whenever the airport in Minneapolis 1034 00:45:17,630 --> 00:45:19,590 would say to Northwest, we want to allow other airlines, 1035 00:45:19,590 --> 00:45:21,320 they'd say, great, we're moving our headquarters out 1036 00:45:21,320 --> 00:45:22,050 of Minneapolis. 1037 00:45:22,050 --> 00:45:23,050 See ya. 1038 00:45:23,050 --> 00:45:25,590 And they'd say, OK, fine, we won't do that. 1039 00:45:25,590 --> 00:45:28,850 So essentially, there became political equilibrium 1040 00:45:28,850 --> 00:45:31,462 where these local airlines were such big employers, 1041 00:45:31,462 --> 00:45:33,170 they'd bully the governments into letting 1042 00:45:33,170 --> 00:45:35,090 them dominate the airports. 1043 00:45:35,090 --> 00:45:37,730 And they essentially recreated a monopoly. 1044 00:45:37,730 --> 00:45:39,590 But the monopoly wasn't on planes. 1045 00:45:39,590 --> 00:45:41,450 It was on airport slots. 1046 00:45:41,450 --> 00:45:45,050 And actually, flying got much more expensive again. 1047 00:45:45,050 --> 00:45:46,742 So the price of flights really came down 1048 00:45:46,742 --> 00:45:48,950 until airlines figured out this hub and spoke system, 1049 00:45:48,950 --> 00:45:50,242 and they've gone back up since. 1050 00:45:50,242 --> 00:45:52,850 Now, they're still cheaper than they were under regulation. 1051 00:45:52,850 --> 00:45:56,660 But roughly speaking, the price fell by more like more than 50% 1052 00:45:56,660 --> 00:45:58,880 initially, and then sort of risen back up. 1053 00:45:58,880 --> 00:46:00,917 It's still lower than it was under regulation. 1054 00:46:00,917 --> 00:46:02,500 But it's risen back up because there's 1055 00:46:02,500 --> 00:46:05,810 this sort of new natural monopoly problem 1056 00:46:05,810 --> 00:46:07,880 that we didn't see. 1057 00:46:07,880 --> 00:46:10,310 So that leads to crazy things, like a price 1058 00:46:10,310 --> 00:46:13,250 of a nonstop to San Francisco today 1059 00:46:13,250 --> 00:46:16,250 is something like half as much from Boston 1060 00:46:16,250 --> 00:46:17,660 as a flight to Minnesota. 1061 00:46:17,660 --> 00:46:18,990 Now, I don't know how your geography skills are, 1062 00:46:18,990 --> 00:46:20,865 but San Francisco's a lot farther from Boston 1063 00:46:20,865 --> 00:46:23,690 than Minnesota is, so it's clearly not a marginal cost 1064 00:46:23,690 --> 00:46:25,100 issue. 1065 00:46:25,100 --> 00:46:26,360 So that's an example. 1066 00:46:26,360 --> 00:46:29,330 It's sort of a nice case study of kind of, 1067 00:46:29,330 --> 00:46:32,360 our motivation was right, by and large economists got it right. 1068 00:46:32,360 --> 00:46:35,510 By and large, we're better off in a deregulated world. 1069 00:46:35,510 --> 00:46:37,145 But not as well off as we thought, 1070 00:46:37,145 --> 00:46:39,520 because we missed this other element of natural monopoly. 1071 00:46:42,890 --> 00:46:44,840 Why don't I stop there. 1072 00:46:44,840 --> 00:46:50,150 We will continue next time by talking about oligopoly.